Favorite betrayal criterion: Difference between revisions

From electowiki
Content added Content deleted
No edit summary
Line 38: Line 38:
==Complying methods==
==Complying methods==


[[Approval voting]], [[range voting]], [[Majority Judgment]], [[MMPO|MinMax(pairwise opposition)]], [[MCA]] (except MCA-A and some versions of MCA-R), [[MAMPO]], and [[Improved Condorcet Approval]] comply with the favorite betrayal criterion.
[[Approval voting]], [[range voting]], [[Majority Judgment]], [[MMPO|MinMax(pairwise opposition)]], [[MCA]] (except MCA-A and some versions of MCA-R), [[MAMPO]], and [[Improved Condorcet Approval]] comply with the favorite betrayal criterion, as do ICT and [[Symmetrical ICT]].


[[Borda count]], [[plurality voting]], [[Condorcet criterion|Condorcet methods]], and [[instant-runoff voting]] do not comply.
[[Borda count]], [[plurality voting]], [[Condorcet criterion|Condorcet methods]], and [[instant-runoff voting]] do not comply.
Line 47: Line 47:


Some complying methods:
Some complying methods:

Approval, Score(also called "Range"), Majority Judgement (MJ), Symmetrical ICT (which see)


An interpretation of this criterion applied to votes as cast is the [[Sincere Favorite criterion]].
An interpretation of this criterion applied to votes as cast is the [[Sincere Favorite criterion]].

Revision as of 02:53, 19 October 2012

The Favorite Betrayal criterion is a criterion for evaluating voting systems.

Here is the FBC definition currently advocated and used by the main advocate of FBC (that would be me):

If no one wins who is not top-voted by you, then, if you move an additional candidate to top, on your ballot, that shouldn't cause someone to win who is not top-voted by you.

[end of FBC definition]

Supplementary definition:

A candidate is "top-voted" by you, and is "at top" on your ballot, if you don't vote anyone over him/her.

[end of definition of "top-voted" and "top"]

The above-stated wording is chosen to allow for ties, (to presumably be later solved randomly), so that the definition will be useful regardless of whether the tie candidates are called "winner", or only the winner of the tiebreaker is called "winner". In other words, the above definition isn't dependent on which of those ways "win" and "winner" are defined.

But if, in the event of a tie, "winner" refers only to the one single candidate who wins after the random tiebreaker has been applied to the tie, then a somewhat more natural and intuitive sounding definition can be written:

If the winner is a candidate whom you've top-voted, then, if you move an additional candidate to top, the winner should still be a candidate top-voted by you.

[end of FBC definition dependent on a particular definition of "winner"]

I prefer the first of those two definitions, because it isn't dependent on how "winner" or "win" is defined. The first of the above two definitions is my definition of FBC.

The definiton written below is the one that I had originally written and used. I liked it, but it led to the question of "What if the way of voting that optimizes your outcome without favorite-burial is some complicated, difficult-to-find strategy?". That question led me to my better definition, written above on this page.

Michael Ossipoff

Definition

A voter optimizes the outcome (from his own perspective) if his vote causes the election of the best possible candidate that can be elected, based on his own preferences, given all the votes cast by other voters.

Statement of the criterion

For any voter who has a unique favorite, there should be no possible set of votes cast by the other voters such that the voter can optimize the outcome (from his own perspective) only by voting someone over his favorite.

Complying methods

Approval voting, range voting, Majority Judgment, MinMax(pairwise opposition), MCA (except MCA-A and some versions of MCA-R), MAMPO, and Improved Condorcet Approval comply with the favorite betrayal criterion, as do ICT and Symmetrical ICT.

Borda count, plurality voting, Condorcet methods, and instant-runoff voting do not comply.

Commentary

Election methods that meet this criterion provide no incentive for voters to betray their favorite candidate by voting another candidate over him or her.

Some complying methods:

An interpretation of this criterion applied to votes as cast is the Sincere Favorite criterion.

Some parts of this article are derived with permission from text at http://electionmethods.org

This page uses Creative Commons Licensed content from Wikipedia (view authors).