Voting system criterion: Difference between revisions

From electowiki
Content added Content deleted
No edit summary
No edit summary
Line 3: Line 3:
A formally defined pass/fail criterion by which a [[voting system]] may be assessed.
A formally defined pass/fail criterion by which a [[voting system]] may be assessed.


== Criterion failure rates ==
Though a voting method may pass or fail a given criterion, that does not mean the voting method can't almost always pass or fail the criterion in practice, or that when it passes or fails the criterion, that this will be particularly bad. Advocates of various voting methods often make the argument that though their method may fail some criteria, that this should not be considered a major drawback of their methods; for example, advocates of [[Approval voting]] and [[IRV]] often argue that though those methods fail the [[Condorcet criterion]], they almost always meet it in practice, and that when they fail it, it is for good reason, or at least not particularly bad.
Though a voting method may pass or fail a given criterion, that does not mean the voting method can't almost always pass or fail the criterion in practice, or that when it passes or fails the criterion, that this will be particularly bad. Advocates of various voting methods often make the argument that though their method may fail some criteria, that this should not be considered a major drawback of their methods; for example, advocates of [[Approval voting]] and [[IRV]] often argue that though those methods fail the [[Condorcet criterion]], they almost always meet it in practice, and that when they fail it, it is for good reason, or at least not particularly bad.


=== Efficiency ===
Many criteria relate to sets of candidates; see the [[set theory]] article for more information.
For some criteria, it is common to use the term "efficient" or "efficiency" to indicate that the criterion is always met by some voting method, or to identify how often that is the case. For example, [[Smith efficiency]] measures how often a voting method passes the [[Smith criterion]].

== Sets ==
Many criteria relate to sets of candidates; see the [[set theory]] article for more information.

Further, a common terminology when comparing two criteria is to say one is stronger than the other when it applies to every situation the other applies to and more (a superset), with weaker meaning it applies to only a subset of the situations.

== Relative importance of various criteria ==


=== Essential criteria ===
Some criteria are very widely agreed to be important. Examples:
Some criteria are very widely agreed to be important. Examples:


Line 13: Line 23:
[[Pareto]]
[[Pareto]]


=== Desirable criteria ===

Other criteria are also widely regarded as good, but there is disagreement over how important it is for a voting method to pass these:
Other criteria are also widely regarded as good, but there is disagreement over how important it is for a voting method to pass these (they are agreed to be desirable, but not necessarily essential):


[[Independence of irrelevant alternatives]]
[[Independence of irrelevant alternatives]]
Line 24: Line 34:
There is disagreement over how important the various other criteria are. Some criteria are even considered bad by some.
There is disagreement over how important the various other criteria are. Some criteria are even considered bad by some.


== Examples ==
Examples for such criteria are:
Examples for such criteria are:


* [[Condorcet Criterion|Condorcet criterion]], [[Consensus Criteria]], [[Consistency|Consistency criterion]], [[Favorite Betrayal criterion]], [[Generalized Strategy-Free criterion]], [[Greatest Possible Consensus Criterion]], [[Independence of irrelevant alternatives|independence from irrelevant alternatives]], [[Independence of irrelevant alternatives|local independence from irrelevant alternatives]], [[Tactical voting|invulnerability to burying]], [[Tactical voting|invulnerability to compromising]], [[Later-no-harm criterion]], [[Monotonicity criterion]], [[Pareto criterion]], [[Participation criterion]], [[Plurality criterion]], [[Schwartz set|Schwartz criterion]], [[Smith set|Smith criterion]] (also known as [[Generalized Condorcet criterion]]), [[Strategic nomination|Independence of clones]], [[Strategy-Free criterion]], [[Strong Defensive Strategy criterion]], [[Summability criterion]], [[Unanimous Consensus Criterion]], [[Weak Defensive Strategy criterion]]
* [[Condorcet Criterion|Condorcet criterion]], [[Consensus Criteria]], [[Consistency|Consistency criterion]], [[Favorite Betrayal criterion]], [[Generalized Strategy-Free criterion]], [[Greatest Possible Consensus Criterion]], [[Independence of irrelevant alternatives|independence from irrelevant alternatives]], [[Independence of irrelevant alternatives|local independence from irrelevant alternatives]], [[Tactical voting|invulnerability to burying]], [[Tactical voting|invulnerability to compromising]], [[Later-no-harm criterion]], [[Monotonicity criterion]], [[Pareto criterion]], [[Participation criterion]], [[Plurality criterion]], [[Schwartz set|Schwartz criterion]], [[Smith set|Smith criterion]] (also known as [[Generalized Condorcet criterion]]), [[Strategic nomination|Independence of clones]], [[Strategy-Free criterion]], [[Strong Defensive Strategy criterion]], [[Summability criterion]], [[Unanimous Consensus Criterion]], [[Weak Defensive Strategy criterion]]


=== Majority-related criteria ===
Here are some criteria often touted by advocates of [[majority rule]], split into categories of "widely agreed on" and criteria which are more polarizing:
Here are some criteria often touted by advocates of [[majority rule]], split into categories of "widely agreed on" and criteria which are more polarizing:


Line 35: Line 47:
[[Condorcet criterion]], [[Smith criterion]]
[[Condorcet criterion]], [[Smith criterion]]


== Types of criteria ==
<br />
=== Absolute criterion ===
=== Absolute criterion ===
An ''absolute criterion'' requires or prohibits some result due to some characteristic of a given a set of ballots. This is in contrast to the below-mentioned [[relative criterion]], which requires (or prohibits) a change in the election's result given some modification to the ballots.
An ''absolute criterion'' requires or prohibits some result due to some characteristic of a given a set of ballots. This is in contrast to the below-mentioned [[relative criterion]], which requires (or prohibits) a change in the election's result given some modification to the ballots.
Line 55: Line 69:


== Notes ==
== Notes ==
For some criteria, it is common to use the term "efficient" or "efficiency" to indicate that the criterion is always met by some voting method, or to identify how often that is the case. For example, [[Smith efficiency]] measures how often a voting method passes the [[Smith criterion]].
=== Proportional Representation ===

[[Proportional representation]] is the general idea that groups of voters with shared preferences should be able to win an amount of representation in a multi-winner body (a legislature) proportional to how large they are. In partisan PR methods, proportionality can be measured using various measures of how well a party's seats matched up to its share of votes. For nonpartisan methods, there is disagreement on how to measure or quantify PR. Ranked PR advocates tend to tout [[Proportionality for Solid Coalitions]], which is meant to account for coherent factions that can be identified from the rankings, while cardinal PR advocates gravitate towards the similar, but weaker, [[Hare quota criterion]] and similar criteria.
[[Proportional representation]] is the general idea that groups of voters with shared preferences should be able to win an amount of representation in a multi-winner body (a legislature) proportional to how large they are. In partisan PR methods, proportionality can be measured using various measures of how well a party's seats matched up to its share of votes. For nonpartisan methods, there is disagreement on how to measure or quantify PR. Ranked PR advocates tend to tout [[Proportionality for Solid Coalitions]], which is meant to account for coherent factions that can be identified from the rankings, while cardinal PR advocates gravitate towards the similar, but weaker, [[Hare quota criterion]] and similar criteria.


=== Rated ballot adaptations ===
Several criteria have rated-ballot or other adaptations that may make more sense in certain contexts. For example, the [[majority criterion]] says that a candidate preferred by a majority over all other candidates must win. The [[Majority criterion for rated ballots]] further requires the majority to give this candidate the highest score. It can be argued that a voter who gives a candidate less than full support doesn't deserve full power, so this modification to the criterion ensures that only a strategic or strongly supportive majority gets their way. Similar adaptations can be made to any criterion involving voter preferences determining who should win, such as [[PSC]], the [[plurality criterion]], [[Mutual majority]], etc.
Several criteria have rated-ballot or other adaptations that may make more sense in certain contexts. For example, the [[majority criterion]] says that a candidate preferred by a majority over all other candidates must win. The [[Majority criterion for rated ballots]] further requires the majority to give this candidate the highest score. It can be argued that a voter who gives their favorite candidate less than full support (i.e. didn't do [[normalization]]) doesn't deserve full power, so this modification to the criterion ensures that only a strategic or strongly supportive majority gets their way. Similar adaptations can be made to any criterion involving voter preferences determining who should win, such as [[PSC]], the [[plurality criterion]], [[Mutual majority]], etc.
[[Category:Voting system criteria|Voting system criteria]]
[[Category:Voting system criteria|Voting system criteria]]
{{fromwikipedia}}
{{fromwikipedia}}

Revision as of 20:49, 14 May 2020

Wikipedia has an article on:

A formally defined pass/fail criterion by which a voting system may be assessed.

Criterion failure rates

Though a voting method may pass or fail a given criterion, that does not mean the voting method can't almost always pass or fail the criterion in practice, or that when it passes or fails the criterion, that this will be particularly bad. Advocates of various voting methods often make the argument that though their method may fail some criteria, that this should not be considered a major drawback of their methods; for example, advocates of Approval voting and IRV often argue that though those methods fail the Condorcet criterion, they almost always meet it in practice, and that when they fail it, it is for good reason, or at least not particularly bad.

Efficiency

For some criteria, it is common to use the term "efficient" or "efficiency" to indicate that the criterion is always met by some voting method, or to identify how often that is the case. For example, Smith efficiency measures how often a voting method passes the Smith criterion.

Sets

Many criteria relate to sets of candidates; see the set theory article for more information.

Further, a common terminology when comparing two criteria is to say one is stronger than the other when it applies to every situation the other applies to and more (a superset), with weaker meaning it applies to only a subset of the situations.

Relative importance of various criteria

Essential criteria

Some criteria are very widely agreed to be important. Examples:

Cloneproofness

Pareto

Desirable criteria

Other criteria are also widely regarded as good, but there is disagreement over how important it is for a voting method to pass these (they are agreed to be desirable, but not necessarily essential):

Independence of irrelevant alternatives

Monotonicity, Participation criterion

Summability criterion

There is disagreement over how important the various other criteria are. Some criteria are even considered bad by some.

Examples

Examples for such criteria are:

Majority-related criteria

Here are some criteria often touted by advocates of majority rule, split into categories of "widely agreed on" and criteria which are more polarizing:

Majority criterion, Mutual majority criterion, Droop proportionality criterion


Condorcet criterion, Smith criterion

Types of criteria


Absolute criterion

An absolute criterion requires or prohibits some result due to some characteristic of a given a set of ballots. This is in contrast to the below-mentioned relative criterion, which requires (or prohibits) a change in the election's result given some modification to the ballots.

Examples of absolute criteria:

Relative criterion

A relative criterion requires that when the ballots are changed in some way, the result of the election must or must not change in some way. This is in contrast to the above-mentioned absolute criterion, which requires some result given some characteristic of a set of ballots.

Examples of relative criteria:

Consensus criterion

Consensus criteria attempt to guarantee the election of consensus candidates. Examples of such criteria include greatest possible consensus criterion and unanimous consensus criterion.

This page is a stub - please add to it.

Notes

Proportional Representation

Proportional representation is the general idea that groups of voters with shared preferences should be able to win an amount of representation in a multi-winner body (a legislature) proportional to how large they are. In partisan PR methods, proportionality can be measured using various measures of how well a party's seats matched up to its share of votes. For nonpartisan methods, there is disagreement on how to measure or quantify PR. Ranked PR advocates tend to tout Proportionality for Solid Coalitions, which is meant to account for coherent factions that can be identified from the rankings, while cardinal PR advocates gravitate towards the similar, but weaker, Hare quota criterion and similar criteria.

Rated ballot adaptations

Several criteria have rated-ballot or other adaptations that may make more sense in certain contexts. For example, the majority criterion says that a candidate preferred by a majority over all other candidates must win. The Majority criterion for rated ballots further requires the majority to give this candidate the highest score. It can be argued that a voter who gives their favorite candidate less than full support (i.e. didn't do normalization) doesn't deserve full power, so this modification to the criterion ensures that only a strategic or strongly supportive majority gets their way. Similar adaptations can be made to any criterion involving voter preferences determining who should win, such as PSC, the plurality criterion, Mutual majority, etc.

This page uses Creative Commons Licensed content from Wikipedia (view authors).