Monroe's method

From Electowiki
Revision as of 18:09, 5 August 2021 by Kristomun (talk | contribs) (Use full name for Warren (as he does in the reference); the linked page now redirects to the Warren Smith article.)
(diff) ← Older revision | Latest revision (diff) | Newer revision → (diff)
Jump to navigation Jump to search

Monroe's method is one of two proportional multi-winner voting methods based on a concept first proposed by Burt Monroe.<ref name="Monroe 1995 pp. 925–940">Monroe, Burt L. (1995). "Fully Proportional Representation". American Political Science Review. Cambridge University Press (CUP). 89 (4): 925–940. doi:10.2307/2082518. ISSN 0003-0554. Retrieved 2020-02-09.<templatestyles src="Module:Citation/CS1/styles.css"></templatestyles></ref>

Concept[edit | edit source]

In the paper, Monroe first defined what he calls pure fully proportional representation or pure FPR. Pure FPR assumes that for each voter <math>v_a</math> and candidate <math>x_i</math>, the amount of misrepresentation <math>v_a</math> incurs were <math>x_i</math> to represent him, is known and defined as <math>\mu_{ia}</math>. If these <math>\mu</math> values are known, then pure FPR consists of assigning a representative to each voter to minimize the total misrepresentation, and then electing these representatives. To quote:

Our objective in pure FPR is to find the set of <math>m</math> representatives, each associated with an equally sized constituency (of <math>\frac{n}{m}</math> voters), for which the total misrepresentation (summed across all voters), <math>\mu</math>, is minimized. In effect, we want voters to define for themselves the group membership or identities that they wish to have represented and to have maximum flexibility in doing so.

Because the actual misrepresentation values usually aren't known, they must be inferred somehow, which is where the two voting methods differ.

Methods[edit | edit source]

Fully Proportional Representation with Ordinal Balloting[edit | edit source]

In <ref name="Monroe 1995 pp. 925–940"/>, Monroe defined an ordinal voting method where the value <math>\mu_{ia}</math> is defined as the rank that <math>v_a</math> ranks <math>x_i</math> (e.g. 1 for a top-ranked candidate, 2 for a candidate ranked second, and so on). Equal-rank is symmetrically completed: each candidate gets a misrepresentation value equal to the average he would've got if the candidates were ranked strictly in a random order. In the single-winner case, FPR with ordinal balloting reduces to the Borda count.

In principle, any weighted positional method can be generalized to an ordinal FPR variant by letting <math>\mu_{ia} = a_1 - a_{rank_{ia}}</math>, where <math>a</math> is the weight vector for that weighted positional method, and <math>rank_{ia}</math> is the rank that <math>v_a</math> gave <math>x_i</math>.

Cardinal method[edit | edit source]

Warren D. Smith later defined a cardinal method based on Monroe's concept.<ref name="RangeVoting.org">Smith, Warren D. (February 2010). "Multiwinner election method based on optimum constrained-degree-subgraph problem". RangeVoting.org. Retrieved 2020-02-09.<templatestyles src="Module:Citation/CS1/styles.css"></templatestyles></ref>

This method maximizes total representation instead of minimizing misrepresentation, and the degree to which a voter is represented by a candidate is simply that voter's rating of the candidate. In the single-winner case, this Monroe method reduces to either Range voting or Approval voting depending on the ballot format.

Following this work a sequential Cardinal method, Sequential Monroe voting, was later invented to simplify this methodology but keep the key requirements.

Variants[edit | edit source]

Chamberlin-Courant[edit | edit source]

The Chamberlin-Courant method works like Monroe, except that the constituencies can be of any size: they are not limited to <math>\frac{n}{m}</math> voters each. This variant is useful for election to a council where each representative has a weighted vote, or for party list PR without thresholds.

Egalitarian Monroe and Chamberlin-Courant[edit | edit source]

Instead of optimizing representation (maximizing representation or minimizing misrepresentation), the egalitarian variants optimize worst misrepresentation: they produce an outcome so that the least represented voter is most represented. Egalitarian Chamberlin-Courant tends to produce consensus outcomes, similar to Minimax approval, while for egalitarian Monroe, the tendency to do so is balanced by its constituency restriction.

Criterion compliances[edit | edit source]

Monroe's method is not house monotone.<ref>Sánchez-Fernández, Luis; Fisteus, Jesús A. (2019-02-22). "Monotonicity axioms in approval-based multi-winner voting rules". arXiv:1710.04246 [cs]: 7.<templatestyles src="Module:Citation/CS1/styles.css"></templatestyles></ref>

Complexity[edit | edit source]

Determining the optimal Monroe outcome is NP-hard but fixed-parameter tractable.<ref name="Procaccia Rosenschein Zohar pp. 353–362">Procaccia, Ariel D.; Rosenschein, Jeffrey S.; Zohar, Aviv (2007-04-19). "On the complexity of achieving proportional representation" (PDF). Social Choice and Welfare. Springer Science and Business Media LLC. 30 (3): 353–362. doi:10.1007/s00355-007-0235-2. ISSN 0176-1714.<templatestyles src="Module:Citation/CS1/styles.css"></templatestyles></ref> There exist constant-factor approximation algorithms for the problem of maximizing representation, but not for minimizing misrepresentation.<ref name="Skowron">Skowron, Piotr Krzysztof; Faliszewski, Piotr; Slinko, Arkadii (2013-06-29). "Fully Proportional Representation as Resource Allocation: Approximability Results". Twenty-Third International Joint Conference on Artificial Intelligence: 357.<templatestyles src="Module:Citation/CS1/styles.css"></templatestyles></ref>

References[edit | edit source]