Single transferable vote: Difference between revisions

 
(21 intermediate revisions by 6 users not shown)
Line 1:
{{Wikipedia}}
 
The '''Singlesingle Transferabletransferable Votevote''', or ('''STV''',) is a [[preferential voting|preferential]] [[voting system]] designed to minimiseminimize [[wasted votes]] in multi-candidate elections while ensuring that votes are explicitly for candidates rather than party lists. It works by assigning candidates votes based on the number of voters who ranked them 1st, electing candidates who reach a certain threshold of votes ("[[quota]]") and spending those votes to ensure as-of-yet unrepresented voters can get someone they like, and otherwise eliminating the candidate with the fewest 1st choices and then treating the uneliminated candidate their voters ranked next-highest as their "new" 1st choice.
 
When promoted as a [[proportional representation]] method in multi-party multi-seat elections, it is generally known as '''Proportional Representation through the Single Transferable Vote''' or '''PR-STV'''. When a similar method is applied to single-seat elections it is sometimes called ''[[instant-runoff voting]]'' or the ''alternative vote'', and has different proportionality implications for a similar ballot.
 
== History ==
{{wikipedia|History and use of the single transferable vote}}
According to English Wikipedia<ref>https://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=History_and_use_of_the_single_transferable_vote&action=history</ref>, this is the history of STV:
<blockquote>
<!--text below copied from https://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=History_and_use_of_the_single_transferable_vote&oldid=1045149797 -->
<!--a picture of an old STV voting machine would go very well here-->The concept of transferable voting was first proposed by [[Thomas Wright Hill]] in 1819.<ref>[[Nicolaus Tideman]], ''Collective Decisions and Voting: The Potential for Public Choice'', Ashgate Publishing Company, Burlington VT, 2006.</ref> The system remained unused in public elections until 1855, when [[Carl Andræ]] proposed a transferable vote system for elections in Denmark.<ref name=humphreys>{{cite book |last1=Humphreys |first1=John H |title=Proportional Representation, A Study in Methods of Election |date=1911 |publisher=Methuen & Co.Ltd |location=London |url=https://archive.org/details/proportionalrepr00humpuoft}}</ref> Andræ's system was used in 1856 to elect the Danish Rigsdag, and by 1866 it was also adapted for indirect elections to the second chamber, the Landsting, until 1915.
 
Although he was not the first to propose a system of transferable votes, the English barrister [[w:Thomas Hare (political scientist)|Thomas Hare]] is generally credited with the conception of Single Transferable Voting, and he may have independently developed the idea in 1857.<ref name=humphreys/> Hare's view was that STV should be a means of "making the exercise of the suffrage a step in the elevation of the individual character, whether it be found in the majority or the minority." In Hare's original STV system, he further proposed that electors should have the opportunity of discovering which candidate their vote had ultimately counted for, to improve their personal connection with voting.<ref name="Lambert">{{cite book|title=Voting in democracies: a study of majority and proportional electoral systems|last1=Lakeman|first1=Enid|last2=Lambert|first2=James D.|year=1959|page=245|publisher=Faber & Faber|oclc=03088530}}
</ref>
 
The noted political essayist, [[w:John Stuart Mill]], was a friend of Hare and an early proponent of STV, praising it in his 1861 essay ''[[w:Considerations on Representative Government]]''. His contemporary, [[w:Walter Bagehot]], also praised the Hare system for allowing everyone to elect an MP, even ideological minorities, but also added that the Hare system would create more problems than it solved: "[the Hare system] is inconsistent with the extrinsic independence as well as the inherent moderation of a Parliament – two of the conditions we have seen, are essential to the bare possibility of parliamentary government."<ref name="Bagehot">{{cite book | last=Bagehot | first=Walter | title=The English Constitution | publisher=Cambridge University Press | publication-place=Cambridge | year=2001 | isbn=978-1-139-16383-5 | doi=10.1017/cbo9781139163835|url=https://socialsciences.mcmaster.ca/econ/ugcm/3ll3/bagehot/constitution.pdf}}
</ref><!-- it's not exactly clear what Bagehot is arguing here... -->
 
STV spread through the British Empire, leading it to be sometimes known as ''British Proportional Representation''. <!-- Think that was noted in Lambert & Lakeman-->In 1896, [[w:Andrew Inglis Clark]] was successful in persuading the Tasmanian House of Assembly to adopt what became known as the ''Hare-Clark system'', named after himself and Thomas Hare.
 
In the 20th century, many refinements were made to Hare's original system, by scholars such as Droop, Meek, Warren and Tideman.
</blockquote>
 
An [[Approval voting]] version of STV was proposed by Gustaf Eneström in 1896.<ref name="Enestrom1896om">{{cite journal|title = Om aritmetiska och statistiska metoder för proportionella val|last = Eneström| first = Gustaf|journal = Öfversigt af Kongliga Vetenskaps-Akademiens Forhandlingar|volume = 53|pages = 543–570|year = 1896}}</ref><ref name="Camps Mora Saumell 2019">{{cite arXiv | last=Camps | first=Rosa | last2=Mora | first2=Xavier | last3=Saumell | first3=Laia | title=The method of Eneström and Phragmén for parliamentary elections by means of approval voting | date=2019-07-23 | eprint=1907.10590 | class=econ.TH}}</ref>
 
== Voting ==
Line 14 ⟶ 34:
#Delilah
 
=== Setting the Quotaquota===
 
When all the votes have been cast, a winning quota is set. The most common formula for the quota is the [[Droop Quota]] which is most often given as:
 
<!-- <math>\left({{\rm votes} \over {\rm seats}+1}\right)+1</math>. -->
floor(votes / (seats + 1)) + 1
 
Other quotas used include the [[Hare Quota]]:
 
<!-- <math>\rm votes \over \rm seats</math> -->
votes / seats
 
When all the votes have been cast, a winning quota is set. In The most common formula fortheory the quota iscan thebe [[Droopany Quota]]number whichin is most often giventhe asrange:
and the [[Imperiali Quota]]:
 
<!-- <math>\rm frac{\text{votes}}{\text{seats} +1} \overleq \rmtext{quota} \leq \frac{\text{votes}}{\text{seats+2} -1} </math>. -->
votes / (seats + 2)
 
ForIn those keeping trackpractice, the sizequota ofis either the [[Droop quota]] isor then generallythe [[Hare > Droop > Imperialiquota]].
 
=== Counting The Votes ===
 
Process A: Top-preference votes are tallied. If one or more candidates have received at least as many votes as the quota, they are declared elected. After a candidate is elected, they may not receive any more votes (though see below for a modernisationmodernization).
 
The excess votes for the winning candidate are reallocated to the next-highest ranked candidates on the ballots for the elected candidate. There are different methods for determining how to reallocate the votes. Some versions use random selection, others count each ballot fractionally.
 
Process A is repeated until there are no more candidates who have reached the quota.
Line 43 ⟶ 52:
Process B: The candidate with the least support is eliminated, and
their votes are reallocated to the next-highest ranked candidates on
the eliminated ballots. After a candidate is eliminated, they may not receive any more votes.
receive any more votes.
 
After each iteration of Process B is completed, Process A starts
Line 74 ⟶ 82:
The threshold is: <!-- <math>\left({30 \over (2+1)}\right) +1 = 11</math> --> floor(30 / (2 + 1)) + 1 = 11.
 
In the first round, Andrea receives 22 votes and Delilah 8. Andrea is
elected with 11 excess votes. Her 11 excess votes are reallocated to their second preferences (which votes are chosen may be decided by random selection). For example, 8 of the reallocated votes are for Carter, 3 for Brad. Note: this is not a realistic example - elections with a small number of votes often have special rules - for example, Irish Senate elections are conducted using thousands of votes.
 
As none of the candidates have reached their threshold, Brad, the
candidate with the fewest votes, is eliminated. All of his votes have
Carter as the next-place choice, and are reallocated to Carter. This
gives Carter 11 votes and he is elected.
 
== Proportionality ==
== Is STV a proportional voting system? ==
STV is perhaps better described as quasi-proportional rather than truly proportional, as it is only proportional in some ways.
 
=== Overall proportionality ===
STV is not a proportional system in the strict sense. STV does not guarantee that a party will get the same percentage of seats as it gets as a percentage of votes. In fact the notion of a vote "for a party" is less meaningful for STV because votes are not necessarily for a single party. A vote can list candidates from an assortment of political parties, in any order. The candidates that are elected reflect the combined preferences of all votes cast.
A major complication with proportionality under STV is the requirement for constituencies, where a set of candidates is elected in each electoral district. Small constituencies are highly disproportional, but large constituencies make it difficult or impossible for voters to rank large numbers of candidates.
 
The proportionality of STV can be controversial, especially in close elections such aslike the [[1981]] election in [[Malta]]. In this election, the Maltese Labour Party won a majority of seats, despite the Nationalist Party winning a majority of ''first preference'' votes. This caused a constitutional crisis, leading to a provision forto theprovide possibilitybonus seats in case of bonusdisproportional seatsresults. These bonus seats were usedneeded in [[1987]], and again in [[1996]]. Similarly, theand [[Northern Ireland Assembly Election2008, 1998|Northernshowing IrelandSTV elections]] inare [[1998]]often leddisproportional to the [[Ulster Unionist]]s winning more seats than the [[Social Democratic and Labour Party]], despite winningat a smaller share of thenational votelevel.
Another complication with proportionality under STV is the constituency system, where a set of candidates is elected in each electoral district. There is no explicit process in STV for balancing the votes between constituencies, so the overall electoral result is merely the sum of the constituency results.
 
Similarly, the Northern Ireland elections in 1998 led to the Ulster Unionists winning more seats than the Social Democratic and Labour Party, despite winning a smaller share of the vote.
Within a constituency, however, STV can be said to be proportional for whatever characteristics the voters valued. For example, if 60% of voters put all the female candidates first, and 40% put all the male candidates first, 60% of the winners would be female and 40% would be male. (Assuming there are sufficient candidates of each gender to make up the numbers.)
 
In the 2020 Irish general elections, the Irish Labour party received 50% more votes than the Social Democrats, but both parties won 6 seats.<ref>{{Cite web|url=https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/2020_Irish_general_election|title=2020 Irish general election|website=Wikipedia|url-status=live}}</ref>
STV provides this proportionality simply by wasting as few votes as possible. A vote is "wasted" if it does not elect anyone; it is partially wasted if it elects someone who gets more votes than is necessary to be elected. STV transfers votes that would otherwise be wasted, and it only transfers such votes.
 
The degree of proportionality nationwide is strongly related to the number of seats to be filled in each constituency. In a three-seat constituency, using the Droop quota, about a quarter of the vote is "wasted". These votes may be for minor candidates that were not eliminated, or elected candidates' surplus votes that did not get redistributed. In a nine-seat constituency, only a tenth of the vote is wasted, and a party needs only 10% of the vote in a constituency to win a seat. Consequently, the best proportionality is achieved when there are a large number of representatives per constituency.
 
=== Within-constituency ===
The proportionality of STV can be controversial, especially in close elections such as the [[1981]] election in [[Malta]]. In this election the Maltese Labour Party won a majority of seats despite the Nationalist Party winning a majority of first preference votes. This caused a constitutional crisis, leading to provision for the possibility of bonus seats. These bonus seats were used in [[1987]] and again in [[1996]]. Similarly, the [[Northern Ireland Assembly Election, 1998|Northern Ireland elections]] in [[1998]] led to the [[Ulster Unionist]]s winning more seats than the [[Social Democratic and Labour Party]], despite winning a smaller share of the vote.
Within a constituency, however, STV can be said to be proportional forif whateverthere characteristicsis thea single characteristic voters valuedvalue above any other. For example, in a five-seat election, if 6051% of voters put all the female candidates first, and 4049% put all the male candidates first, 60% of the winners (three out of five) would be female andwith 40%the wouldDroop bequota, male.whereas (Assumingsomewhere therebetween are40% sufficientand candidates60% ofwould eachbe genderfemale tounder makeHare up(depending on the numbers.precise allocation of votes).
 
STV provides this proportionality by reassigning votes to later preferences in a way that avoids waste. A vote is considered [[Wasted vote|wasted]] if it is not used to elect anyone, i.e. if it is not held by a winning candidate at the end of the count.
Advocates of STV argue that the apparent disproportionality in STV is indicative of poor support for the party's candidates in second and third preferences. They argue that the STV result is actually a more accurate estimate of the party's support than a simple tally of first-preference votes.
 
Within each constituency, STV passes the [[Droop proportionality criterion]]for whensolid using [[Hagenbach-Bischoff quota|Hagenbach-Bischoff quotascoalitions]]. (when doing so, it is suggested that a candidate win only if they exceed quota), because whenWhen all but k candidates of a solid coalition's supported candidates have been eliminated, one of the remaining candidates is now the 1st choice of over a quota of voters, and is thus elected, with. theirTheir surplus votes flowingflow towards some of the other k candidates, and this repeating,repeats until all k candidates are elected. This guarantees a majority will win at least half of the seats in each constituency.
 
STV violates most axioms of proportional representation other than [[Proportionality for Solid Coalitions|proportionality for solid coalitions]].
== Potential for Tactical Voting ==
 
== Potential for Tacticaltactical Votingvoting ==
The single transferable vote eliminates much of the reason for [[tactical voting]]. Voters are "safe" voting for a candidate they fear won't be elected,
because their votes will be reallocated in Process B. They are "safe" voting for a candidate they believe will receive overwhelming support, because their votes
will get reallocated in Process A.
 
The single transferable vote eliminates much of the reason for [[tactical voting]]. Voters are "safe" voting for a candidate they fear won't be elected, because their votes will be reallocated in Process B. They are "safe" voting for a candidate they believe will receive overwhelming support, because their votes will get reallocated in Process A.
However, in older STV systems there is a loophole:
 
candidates who have already been elected do not receive any more votes, so there is incentive to avoid voting for your top-ranked candidate until after they have already been elected. For example, a voter might make a tactical decision to rank their top-place candidate beneath a candidate they know will lose (perhaps a fictional candidate). If the voter's true top-place candidate has not been elected by the time their fake top candidate loses, the voter's full vote will count for their true top-place candidate. Otherwise, the
However, in older STV systems there is a loophole: candidates who have already been elected do not receive any more votes, so there is incentive to avoid voting for your top-ranked candidate until after they have already been elected. For example, a voter might make a tactical decision to rank their top-place candidate beneath a candidate they know will lose (perhaps a fictional candidate). If the voter's true top-place candidate has not been elected by the time their fake top candidate loses, the voter's full vote will count for their true top-place candidate. Otherwise, the voter will have avoided having had their ballot in the lottery to be "[[wasted vote]]s" on their top-ranked candidate, and will continue on to lower-ranked candidates.
 
Note that in more modern STV systems, this loophole has been fixed. A vote receives the same fractional weighting regardless of when it arrives at the successful candidate. This modernisation has not been adopted in all STV systems.
 
There are also tactical considerations for parties standing more than one candidate in the election. Standing too few may result in all the candidates being elected in the early stages, and votes being transferred to candidates of other parties. Standing too many candidates might result in first-preference votes being spread amongst them, and several being eliminated before any are elected and their second-preference votes distributed, if voters do not stick tightly to their preferred party's candidates; however, if voters vote for all candidates from a particular party before any other candidates and before stopping expressing preferences, then too many candidates is not an issue - in Malta where voters tend to strictly express party preference, parties frequently stand more candidates than there are seats to be elected.
 
[[Vote management]] is a potential strategy in STV that involves [[Bullet voting|bullet voting]] in a way that approximates [[D'Hondt]] to maximize a party's seat share. 5-winner example:
Line 141 ⟶ 150:
* New Zealand [http://www.stv.govt.nz], where STV is being used for the first time for district health board and some local authority elections in October 2004
* Northern Ireland, for local, Assembly and European elections
* The United States, where the only official governing bodies that use STV to elect representatives are the City Council and School Committee of [[Cambridge, Massachusetts]].
 
STV enjoyed some popularity in the United States in the first half of the 20th Century. TheIt communitywas schoolused boards ofin the City of New York council elections [[New_York#Single_transferable_vote|from 1937 to 1947]]. The community school boards of the city [http://ccrc.wustl.edu/~lorracks/projects/techreport/subsection3_4_4.html] also used STV until they were abolished in 2002.
 
The method used for electing the Legislative Assemblies of Tasmania and the elections in the province of Alberta, Canada from 1926 to 1955.
Line 149 ⟶ 158:
British Columbia will decide in 2005 by referendum whether to adopt STV to replace its current [[First Past the Post]] electoral system, after a recommendation of STV [http://www.citizensassembly.bc.ca/public/news/2004/10/dmaclachlan-3_0410241345-701] by the Citizens' Assembly on Electoral Reform.
 
Some non-governmental organisations also use STV. For instance, all National Union of Students of the United Kingdom elections and those of their constituent members are under the system.
 
==Historical assessments==
Line 157 ⟶ 166:
 
=== Quotas ===
* [[Hare quota]] (most proportional)
* [[Droop quota]] (most common)
* [[Ross quota]]{{Cn}}{{Clarify|reason=WTF is a Ross quota|date=April 2024}}
* [[Imperiali quota]]
* [[Hagenbach-Bischoff quota]] (sometimes also called a Droop quota)
* [[Ross quota]]
 
=== Ways of dealing with equal rankings ===
* Disallowing them, requiring full rankings.
* Counting a ballot with N top-ranked candidates as a single vote for one of them chosen at random. This approach could be used for a manual count with a large number of ballots to make the counting process easier. There's no reason to use it with computer counting, and it shouldn't be used if there are only a few ballots to count.
*Giving one vote to one of the top-ranked candidates, and giving no vote to the other top-ranked candidates (likely best done by choosing randomly which top-ranked candidate gets the vote)
* ER-STV (fractional): Counting a ballot with N top-ranked candidates as 1/N of a vote for each candidate.
* ER-STV (whole votes) or Approval-STV: Giving one vote to each equally-top-ranked candidate. Can optionally be combined with a suggestion that ballots that equally rank candidates shouldn't be able to prevent the elimination of those candidates.<ref name="reddit 2011">{{cite web | title=Proportionality failure in STV with equal-ranks with whole votes : EndFPTP | website=reddit | date=2019-12-05 | url=https://www.reddit.com/r/EndFPTP/comments/e6bt6s/proportionality_failure_in_stv_with_equalranks/f9thuy4/?context=8&depth=9 | access-date=2020-02-10}}</ref>
 
The nature of STV is such that many of its derived properties depend on each voter exerting influence such that their support for all candidates adds up to at most "one vote" (see [[:Category:FPTP-based voting methods|Category:FPTP-based voting methods]]). Thus, fractional equal-ranking preserves most of IRV's criterion compliances and properties, but not Approval-IRV. In addition, fractional equal-ranking creates less ambiguity around how to configure the IRV rules, whereas with Approval-IRV, different variations of the rules which would give the same results with other forms of IRV can give different results:
 
Note that in the single-winner case, giving a vote to each equally-top ranked candidate can lead to different results when using either the "if in any round any candidate gets a quota (if using a Droop quota, a majority, in the single-winner case) they win" rule or the "all but ((number of winners) + 1) candidates must be eliminated, with the (number of winners) candidate(s) with the most votes then winning" rule (which can also be thought of as "all but (number of winners) candidates must be eliminated, with the remaining candidate(s) winning"). Single-winner example: <blockquote>45 A=C>B
Line 173 ⟶ 182:
35 B>A>C
 
20 C>B>A </blockquote>If the first rule is used (modified to also say "if multiple candidates have Droop quotas in the same round, the candidate(s) with the largest Droop quotas win"), then C wins with 65 votes to start off with, whereas under the second rule, B is eliminated, and then A wins. The second rule can actually create greater possibility for [[Tactical voting#Types of tactical voting|pushover]] strategy, since it could have been the case the A=C>B voters' honest preferences were A>B>C, and if they had voted their honest preference, C would've been eliminated and then B would've won, a worse result from their point of view. Also, this can lead to different results when using either the "all candidates who reach quota are elected" rule or the "the candidate who most exceeds the quota is elected, then spend their ballots, and repeat" rule. 3-winner example with Droop quotas: <blockquote>34 A=B=C
 
Also, this can lead to different results when using either the "all candidates who reach quota are elected" rule or the "the candidate who most exceeds the quota is elected, then spend their ballots, and repeat" rule. 3-winner example with Droop quotas: <blockquote>34 A=B=C
 
33 D
Line 182 ⟶ 189:
 
=== Methods of transferring excess votes ===
If the quota is 100 votes and a candidate wins with 250 votes:
 
* Random transfer: 100 ballots are randomly chosen from the pool of 250 and "spent", with the other 150 being transferred to their next-highest-uneliminated preferred candidate.
There are several possible variations of [[Surplus Handling]]
* Fractional transfer: 100/250=40% of all 250 ballots is spent, with all 250 ballots now supporting their next-highest-uneliminated preferred candidate, but with only 60% ballot weight/power. There are several possible variations of [[Surplus Handling]]
 
=== Ways of choosing a candidate to eliminate ===
* Standard STV: Eliminate the candidate with the fewest top-choice votes.
* [[BTR-STV]]: Eliminate the pairwise loser of the bottom two candidates. (meetsMeets the [[Condorcet criterion]] in single-winner elections).
* [[Benham's method|Benham]]: If the candidate with the fewest top-choice votes beats every other remaining candidate pairwise, eliminate the candidate with the next fewest top-choice votes. Meets the [[Condorcet criterion]] in single-winner elections.
* [[STV-CLE]]: Eliminate the loser of a [[Condorcet ranking]] or a [[Condorcet method]]'s ranking. Using a Condorcet method that passes [[local independence of irrelevant alternatives]] can lend additional stability to the STV method.
 
=== Methods of transferring votes from an eliminated candidate === <!-- Meek, Warren, Gregory, random transfer go here, or into "transferring excess votes", at some point -->
Line 205 ⟶ 214:
4. Eliminate the candidate with the fewest 1st choices and redistribute their voters' votes to their next preferences. Go to step 2.
 
* Conceptually speaking, the candidates who are eliminated during the STV portion of the count could be said to be eliminated from contention for the first N - 1 seats, but still remain in contention for the final seat; though technically, it's possible for the final seat to be filled during the STV count itself (i.e. in a 2-seat election, 2 candidates might each have a quota of 1st choices and automatically win).<ref name="reddit pseudo">{{cite web | title=Pseudocode for STV with Condorcet for the final seat : EndFPTP | website=reddit | date=2020-02-08 | url=https://www.reddit.com/r/EndFPTP/comments/f0muwv/pseudocode_for_stv_with_condorcet_for_the_final/ | access-date=2020-02-10}}</ref></blockquote>IfNote thethat single-winnerwith method passes the [[Majority criterion|majoritythis criterion]]scheme, thenafter thisall modificationbut makesone STVseat withis Droopfilled, quotassurplus becomedistribution theis single-winneronly methodnecessary inwhen thethere single-winneris case,enough sinceof a candidatesurplus withto apotentially Droophelp quotaone of 1st choices is the majority'suneliminated 1stcandidates choiceget ina the single-winner casequota. If STV with Hare Quotas is used instead, then this modification can be used with any single-winner method that passes [[Pareto criterion|unanimity]] and reduce to that single-winner method in the single-winner case.
 
If the single-winner method passes the [[majority criterion]], then this modification makes STV with Droop quotas become the single-winner method in the single-winner case, since a candidate with a Droop quota of 1st choices is the majority's 1st choice in the single-winner case. If STV with Hare quotas is used instead, then this modification can be used with any single-winner method that passes [[Pareto criterion|unanimity]] and reduce to that single-winner method in the single-winner case.
 
5-winner example:<blockquote>45 L1 > L2 > L3 > C > R2 > R1
Line 231 ⟶ 242:
15 D>A>B>C</blockquote>E has a Droop quota (51 votes) so they win, and their 51 supporters' ballots are spent. Then we run a majority-passing single-winner method, say, [https://en.m.wikipedia.org/wiki/Mutual_majority_criterion#Minimax Minimax] on the remaining 100 ballots, and D wins despite there being a Droop solid coalition and thus a [[Mutual majority criterion|mutual majority]] of 52 voters for (A, B, C). Only a mutual majority-passing single-winner method would guarantee one of A, B, and C wins.
 
This modification to STV addresses to some extent one of the criticisms made by STV advocates about single-winner methods other than IRV:<blockquote>Furthermore, approval, score, and Condorcet were all designed to be used in single-winner elections only. Ranked choice voting works well for both single-winner ''and'' multi-winner elections. For elections that involve a mixture of single-winner and multi-winner races, we strongly prefer the simplicity of using a uniform voting method across the board.<ref>{{Cite web|url=https://www.fairvote.org/how_is_rcv_better_than_approval_score_or_condorcet_voting_methods|title=How is RCV better than Approval, Score or Condorcet voting methods?|last=FairVote.org|website=FairVote|access-date=2020-05-19}}</ref></blockquote>{{sectstub}}
 
== Notes ==
STV is a [[Largest remainder method|largest remainder method]] in the [[Party list case|party list case]]. This is because it gives each party as many seats as they have quotas, and when nobody can reach the quota anymore, it eliminates candidates until there are only as many candidates left as seats that are still unfilled, which de facto means that the parties with the most votes remaining (i.e. largest remainders) will win, since they'll be last to be eliminated.
 
STV and IRV can be visualized using Sankey or flow diagrams. If, in a given round, a candidate reaches the quota (a majority in IRV), they win, and if more seats are to be filled, then a quota of their votes are spent. This could be visualized by arranging the candidates from most votes to fewest in each round, and then showing a threshold for how many votes the candidate with the most votes in that round needs to win, or even further, showing the quota needed for the top (number of seats to be filled) candidates to win. Here is one example: <ref>{{Cite web|url=https://www.reddit.com/r/dataisbeautiful/comments/8we8ep/sankey_diagram_of_results_from_maines_democratic/|title=r/dataisbeautiful - Sankey diagram of results from Maine's Democratic Gubernatorial Primary, the state's first election using Ranked Choice Voting [OC]|website=reddit|language=en-US|access-date=2020-05-19}}</ref>
 
STV passes [[PSC]] regardless of the method used to decide which candidate is to be eliminated next, because for a solid coalition comprising k quotas, once all but k of the candidates in the coalition are eliminated, at least one of the k remaining candidates will have a quota of 1st choices and win, with their surplus transferring if necessary such that another of the k candidates wins, etc. It passes the [[Droop proportionality criterion]] when the [[Droop quota]] is used, making it one of the few commonly discussed PR methods that guarantees that a majority will always win at least half of the seats.
 
STV has several variations that can be discussed. For example, Meek and Warren STV are variants of STV that attempt to make the process fairer, but at the cost of needing to be computerized to compute the result.
 
There is some discussion regarding how to make STV results more transparent, while limiting the ability of vote-riggers to identify specific voters by having access to all of the preference data. <ref name="Lee">{{cite journal|last=Naish|first=Lee|title=Partial disclosure of votes in STV elections|journal=Voting matters|volume=30|pages=9-13|year=2013|url=http://www.votingmatters.org.uk/ISSUE30/I30P2.pdf}}</ref>
=== Related Election Methods ===
 
=== Related Electionelection Methodsmethods ===
*[[SNTV|Single Non-Transferable Vote]]
* [[CPO-STV]]
Line 264 ⟶ 277:
[[Category:FPTP-based voting methods]]
[[Category:PSC-compliant voting methods]]
[[Category:Largest remainder-reducing voting methodmethods]]