Strategy-free criterion: Difference between revisions

definition template
imported>WikipediaBot
m (importing text from Wikipedia)
 
(definition template)
 
(13 intermediate revisions by 9 users not shown)
Line 1:
The '''strategy-free criterion''' is a [[voting system criterion]] for evaluating [[voting system]]s.
<h4 class=left>Definitions</h4>
 
== Definitions ==
<p>A sincere vote is one with no falsified preferences or preferences left unspecified when the election method allows them to be specified (in addition to the preferences already specified).</p>
 
<p>A sincere vote is one with no falsified preferences or preferences left unspecified when the election method allows them to be specified (in addition to the preferences already specified).</p>
<p>One candidate is preferred over another candidate if, in a one-on-one competition, more voters prefer the first candidate than prefer the other candidate.</p>
 
<p>If oneOne candidate is preferred over eachanother ofcandidate theif, otherin candidatesa one-on-one competition, thatmore candidatevoters isprefer calledthe "Condorcetfirst candidate" orthan "Condorcetprefer winner"the other candidate.</p>
 
If one candidate is preferred over each of the other candidates, that candidate is called "Condorcet candidate" or "Condorcet winner".
<h4 class=left>Statement of Criterion</h4>
 
== Statement of criterion ==
<p><em>If a Condorcet candidate exists, and if a majority
prefers this candidate to another candidate, then the other candidate should
not win if that majority votes sincerely and no other voter falsifies
any preferences.</em></p>
 
{{definition|If a Condorcet candidate exists, and if a majority prefers this candidate to another candidate, then the other candidate should not win if that majority votes sincerely and no other voter falsifies any preferences.}}
[[Category:Voting system criteria]]
In a ranked method, it is nearly equivalent to say: {{definition|If more than half of the voters rank ''x'' above ''y'', and there is no candidate ''z'' whom more than half of the voters rank above ''x'', then ''y'' must not be elected.}}
 
<h4 class=left>= Complying Methods</h4>methods ==
 
*'''Complies''': [[Schulze method]] (with winning votes as the measure of defeat strength), [[MDDA]], [[MAMPO]]
<p>[[Cloneproof Schwartz Sequential Dropping]] complies with the Strategy-Free Criterion, while*'''Fails''': [[Approval voting]], [[Cardinal Ratings]], [[Borda count]], [[Plurality voting]], and [[Instant-Runoff Voting]] do not comply.</p>
 
<h4 class=left>= Commentary</h4> ==
 
<p>The reader may be wondering how the Condorcet candidate, if one exists, could
possibly <em>''not</em>'' be preferred by a majority of voters over any
other candidate. The key is that some voters may have no preference
between a given pair of candidates. Out of 100 voters, for example, 45
Line 29 ⟶ 27:
prefer the opposite, with the other 15 having no preference between the
two. In that case, it is not true that a majority of voters prefer the
Condorcet candidate over the other candidate, and SFC does not apply.</p>
 
<p>In order to understand SFC, one must also understand that there are
two types of insincere votes: false preferences and truncated
preferences. Voters <em>''truncate</em>'' by terminating their rank list
before their true preferences are fully specified (note that the last
choice is always implied, so leaving it out is not considered
truncation). Voters <em>''falsify</em>'' their preferences, on the other
hand, by reversing the order of their true preferences or by specifying
a preference they don't really have. Suppose, for example, that a
voter's true preferences are (A,B,C,D). Thewith voteno (A)preference orbetween (A,B)D wouldand be aE.
The vote (A) or (A,B) would be a truncated vote, and the vote (B,A,C) or (A,C,B) would be a falsified
or (A,B,C,D,E) would be a falsified vote.
vote.</p>
 
<p>SFC requires that the majority of voters who prefer the Condorcet candidate to
another particular candidate vote sincerely (neither falsify nor
truncate their preferences), and it also requires that no other voter
Line 50 ⟶ 48:
candidate to win by truncating their preferences. (In theory, that
minority could cause the other candidate to win by falsifying their
preferences, but that would be a very risky <em>''offensive</em>'' strategy
that is more likely to backfire than to succeed.) The significance of
the SFC guarantee is that the majority has no need for defensive
strategy, hence the name Strategy-Free Criterion.</p>
 
The [[Schulze method]] was shown to comply with both the Condorcet and Generalized Condorcet Criteria (CC and GCC) above. Although compliance with CC and GCC are important, those criteria apply only in the theoretically ideal case in which all votes are sincere. The Strategy-Free criterion goes further and shows that, under certain reasonable conditions, a majority of voters have no incentive to vote insincerely. The fact that the [[Schulze method]] also complies with SFC therefore enhances the significance of CC and GCC considerably.
<p>[[Cloneproof Schwartz Sequential Dropping]] was shown to comply with both the
Condorcet and Generalized Condorcet Criteria (CC and GCC) above.
Although compliance with CC and GCC are important, those criteria apply
only in the theoretically ideal case in which all votes are sincere. The
Strategy-Free criterion goes further and shows that, under certain
reasonable conditions, a majority of voters have no incentive to vote
insincerely. The fact that [[Cloneproof Schwartz Sequential Dropping]] also complies with SFC
therefore enhances the significance of CC and GCC considerably.</p>
 
''Some parts of this article are derived with permission from text at http://electionmethods.org''
 
== See Alsoalso ==
 
*[[Voting system]]
Line 79 ⟶ 70:
*[[Summability criterion]]
 
== External Linkslinks ==
 
* [http://electionmethods.org/ Election Methods Education and Research Group]
 
* [http://electionmethods.org/ Election Methods Education and Research Groupelectionmethods.org]
{{fromwikipedia}}
[[Category:Voting system criteria]]