D'Hondt method: Difference between revisions

m
Change D'Hondt to d'Hondt per the Oxford Reference: https://www.oxfordreference.com/view/10.1093/oi/authority.20110803095715357. Do some more cleanup and add Phragmén's method.
m (Change D'Hondt to d'Hondt per the Oxford Reference: https://www.oxfordreference.com/view/10.1093/oi/authority.20110803095715357. Do some more cleanup and add Phragmén's method.)
 
(5 intermediate revisions by 3 users not shown)
Line 1:
{{Wikipedia}}
 
The '''d'Hondt method''' or the Jefferson method (both are equivalent, but described differently) is a highest averages method for allocating seats. This system favors large parties slightly more than the other popular [[divisor method]], [[Sainte-Laguë method|Sainte-Laguë]], does. The method described is named in the United States after Thomas Jefferson, who introduced the method for proportional allocation of seats in the United States House of Representatives in 1792, and in Europe after Belgian mathematician Victor Dd'Hondt, who described the methodology in 1878.
 
It is used in: Argentina, Austria, Bulgaria, Chile, Denmark (for local elections), Finland, Israel, the Netherlands, Poland, Portugal and Spain, as well as elections to the European Parliament in some countries. The method is named after Belgian mathematician [[Victor d'Hondt]]. Jefferson's method is named after Thomas Jefferson, and was used to apportion the U.S. House of Representatives between 1792 and 1840.
The '''d'Hondt method''' or the Jefferson method (both are equivalent, but described differently) is a highest averages method for allocating seats. This system favors large parties slightly more than the other popular [[divisor method]], [[Sainte-Laguë method|Sainte-Laguë]], does. The method described is named in the United States after Thomas Jefferson, who introduced the method for proportional allocation of seats in the United States House of Representatives in 1792, and in Europe after Belgian mathematician Victor D'Hondt, who described the methodology in 1878.
 
It is used in: Argentina, Austria, Bulgaria, Chile, Denmark (for local elections), Finland, Israel, the Netherlands, Poland, Portugal and Spain, as well as elections to the European Parliament in some countries. The method is named after Belgian mathematician [[Victor d'Hondt]]. Jefferson's method is named after Thomas Jefferson, and was used to apportion the U.S. House of Representatives between 1792 and 1840.
 
==Allocation==
Line 27 ⟶ 26:
As a simple example, if there are 2 seats to be filled, with Party A having 300 votes and Party B having 290 votes, then Party A wins the first seat, with their new vote total becoming 150 votes (calculated as 300/((1)+1) = 300/2). This means Party A now has 150 votes and Party B has 290 votes, so Party B wins the second seat, and the procedure is over.
 
A larger example (<font color="#FF0000">red</font> indicates that party won a seat in that round because it had the most votes of any party in that round; this table can be thought of as going in "rounds", with the first round showing how many votes each party had, and each successive round showing how many votes each party had after applying the Dd'Hondt procedure):<table width="100%" border="0" cellspacing="0" cellpadding="0">
<tr>
<td><div align="right"></div></td>
Line 120 ⟶ 119:
==Variations==
 
The Hagenbach-Bischoff system is equivalent to, and is a faster way of doing Dd'Hondt: It works by first assigning each party as many seats as they have [[Hagenbach-Bischoff quota|Hagenbach-Bischoff quotas]], and then running Dd'Hondt with the recognition of the seats already won by each party.
 
In some cases, a [[election threshold|threshold]] or ''barrage'' is set, and any list which does not receive that threshold will not have any seats allocated to it, even if it received enough votes to otherwise have been rewarded with a seat. Examples of countries using this threshold are Israel (1.5%) and Belgium (5%, on regional basis).
 
Some systems allow parties to associate their lists together into a single ''cartel'' in order to overcome the threshold, while some systems set a separate threshold for cartels. Smaller parties often form pre-election [[coalition]]scoalitions to make sure they get past the election threshold.
 
== Jefferson's method ==
Jefferson's method is equivalent to Dd'Hondt, but is described differently: <blockquote>Choose a divisor D. A state with population N (or a political party with N seats) is entitled to floor(N/D) seats. If the number of seats allocated equals the size of the legislative body, then use the apportionment just calculated. Otherwise, choose a new value for D and try again.</blockquote>Example: In 1790, the U.S. had 15 states. For the purpose of allocating seats in the House of Representatives, the state populations were as follows:
{| class="wikitable"
!State
Line 284 ⟶ 283:
!60
|}
 
== Computational complexity ==
Let <math>s</math> be the number of seats and <math>r</math> be the number of parties. The standard sequential allocation procedure determines the outcome in <math>O(s \log r)</math> time. More sophisticated algorithms can determine the outcome in <math>O(r \log r)</math> time.<ref name="Gall 2003 pp. 325–333">{{cite journal | last=Gall | first=Françoise Le | title=Determination of the modes of a Multinomial distribution | journal=Statistics & Probability Letters | publisher=Elsevier BV | volume=62 | issue=4 | year=2003 | issn=0167-7152 | doi=10.1016/s0167-7152(02)00430-3 | pages=332-333}}</ref><ref name="White Hendy 2010 pp. 63–68">{{cite journal | last=White | first=W.T.J. | last2=Hendy | first2=M.D. | title=A fast and simple algorithm for finding the modes of a multinomial distribution | journal=Statistics & Probability Letters | publisher=Elsevier BV | volume=80 | issue=1 | year=2010 | issn=0167-7152 | doi=10.1016/j.spl.2009.09.013 | pages=63–68}}</ref>
 
== Extensions of theory ==
 
One of the only ranked PR methods that reduces to d'Hondt in its [[party list case]] is [[Schulze STV]]. Several [[cardinal PR]] methods reduce to d'Hondt if certain divisors are used. Some of these are:
 
* [[Phragmen's voting rules|Phragmén's method]]
* [[Reweighted Range Voting|Reweighted Range voting]]
* [[Sequential proportional approval voting]]
* [[Single distributed vote]]
 
== Notes ==
Parties can generally guarantee themselves at least as many seats as they would get in Dd'Hondt in any PR method by doing [[Vote management|vote management]]. In fact, an alternative way to visualize Dd'Hondt is to see how many seats each party could guaranteeably win if doing vote management. One thing that can help in this visualization is that all [[Highest averages method|Highest averages methods]] pass [[House monotonicity criterion|House monotonicity]], therefore they can all be visualized as simply filling one seat at a time with no change to the result. Example:
 
A 10 B 7 C 4 D 3
Line 294 ⟶ 305:
'''A 5 A 5''' B 7 C 4 D 3
 
In other words, now that A got the first seat, they are "looking to play" for two seats; they are seeing if they can secure two seats no matter what the other parties do with their votes. Notice that the idea of the division is that if the other parties try to take the one seat that A has, then A can re-fuse its votes to ensure they have more votes than the other parties. B gets the second seat and the votes become:
 
A 5 A 5 '''B 3.5 B 3.5''' C 4 D 3
Line 304 ⟶ 315:
etc.
 
The reason Dd'Hondt guarantees every party at least as many seats as they have more voters than that number of HB quotas, thus satisfying the [[Droop proportionality criterion]], is because there is always 1 HB quota more than the number of seats, so when a party has more voters than k HB quotas, it can divide its votes to do more than a quota per seat for k seats, whereas all other parties combined can at most do just under (((total number of seats + 1)-k)/(number of seats - (k - 1))) i.e. the most votes the other parties can have divided by the number of seats they're trying to take. For example, if there are 10 seats to be filled, and one party has over 3 HB quotas, then they can take at least 3 seats because they can do over 1 quota per seat for 3,and for all other parties to take at least (10-(3-1))=8 seats (the minimum required for them to deny the other party 3 seats, since you can't get 3 seats if 8 out of 10 seats are already allotted), the other parties can do at most just under ((10+1)-3)/8)=1 quota per seat for 8 seats.
 
The divisor in Dd'Hondt will always be equal to or smaller than a [[Hare quota]], because that is the largest divisor possible such that there are only as many winners as seats to be filled.
 
One easy way to do Dd'Hondt in certain simple examples is to compare all parties except the party with the fewest votes (the last-place party) with the last-place party; if all other parties can split more votes per seat than the last-place party has for even one seat such that all other parties would be able to win a combined number of seats equal to or greater than the number of seats to be filled, then the last-place party can be eliminated, and this procedure repeated, to find a minimum number of seats each party must win in Dd'Hondt. Example: Suppose there are 8 seats to be filled, and 4 parties, A through D, with the votes being (in descending order) A: 10, B: 8, C: 3, and D: 2. Start by dividing every party's votes by just over the last-place party's (D's) vote total (just over 2). Each party can put more than 2 votes per seat for this number of seats: A: 4 (10/2 = 5, which moved down to the next-closest integer is 4), B: 3 (8/2 = 4, shifted down = 3), and C: 1 (3/2 = 1.5 shifted down = 1). In total, these parties have 4 + 3 + 1 seats; this is the number of seats desired, therefore, this is the final result.<br />One of the only ranked PR methods that reduces to D'Hondt in its [[party list case]] is [[Schulze STV]]. Several [[cardinal PR]] methods reduce to D'Hondt if certain divisors are used.
The divisor in D'Hondt will always be equal to or smaller than a [[Hare quota]], because that is the largest divisor possible such that there are only as many winners as seats to be filled.
 
== References ==
One easy way to do D'Hondt in certain simple examples is to compare all parties except the party with the fewest votes (the last-place party) with the last-place party; if all other parties can split more votes per seat than the last-place party has for even one seat such that all other parties would be able to win a combined number of seats equal to or greater than the number of seats to be filled, then the last-place party can be eliminated, and this procedure repeated, to find a minimum number of seats each party must win in D'Hondt. Example: Suppose there are 8 seats to be filled, and 4 parties, A through D, with the votes being (in descending order) A: 10, B: 8, C: 3, and D: 2. Start by dividing every party's votes by just over the last-place party's (D's) vote total (just over 2). Each party can put more than 2 votes per seat for this number of seats: A: 4 (10/2 = 5, which moved down to the next-closest integer is 4), B: 3 (8/2 = 4, shifted down = 3), and C: 1 (3/2 = 1.5 shifted down = 1). In total, these parties have 4 + 3 + 1 seats; this is the number of seats desired, therefore, this is the final result.<br />One of the only ranked PR methods that reduces to D'Hondt in its [[party list case]] is [[Schulze STV]]. Several [[cardinal PR]] methods reduce to D'Hondt if certain divisors are used.
<references />
 
[[Category:Party list theory]]
1,204

edits