Summability criterion: Difference between revisions

Created a formal-ish expression of the "summability criterion" that is hopefully understandable to typical voters (and is hopefully accurate)
(Noting that the "summability criterion" is frequently referred to as "precinct summability")
(Created a formal-ish expression of the "summability criterion" that is hopefully understandable to typical voters (and is hopefully accurate))
Line 1:
{{wikipedia|Summability criterion}}
The '''summability criterion''' (sometimes referred to as "'''precinct summability'''" or "'''batch summability'''"<ref>{{Cite web |title=Q: Are STAR Voting ballots "summable," or do they require centralized tabulation? |url=https://www.starvoting.org/summable |access-date=2022-12-25 |website=STAR Voting |language=en}}</ref>) is a criterion about the vote-counting process of [[Electoral system|electoral systems]],. which describesFor howbatch precinct-summablesummability ato votingbe method is. Unlike most other voting system criteriatrue, it does not relate to the endfollowing result,must onlybe totrue: the process.
 
*Say that candidates "A", "B", and "C" run against each other in an arbitrary election using single-winner electoral system "S"
*Say that candidate "A" wins in batch "X" (or precinct "X") when ballots are tabulated using single-winner electoral system "S"
*Say that candidate "A" wins in batch "Y" (or precinct "Y") when ballots are tabulated using single-winner electoral system "S"
*Therefore, candidate "A" must win when batches "X" and "Y" of ballots are tabulated using single-winner electoral system "S" for "S" to be "batch summable" (and thus, pass the "summability criterion")
 
Unlike most other voting system criteria, it does not relate to the end result, only to the process.
 
This is important for elections with many voting jurisdictions to be able to practically transmit their vote totals for tabulation. Summability is important to be able to report real-time combined vote totals in an understandable way. Some non-summable methods require that the individual ballot images are are transmitted to a centralized counting location to find the combined result.
==Compliance ==
Back in 2009, [[English Wikipedia]] stated that the criterion was stated as follows:<ref>An article titled "[[wikipedia:Summability criterion|Summability criterion]]" was deleted from [[English Wikipedia]] in 2009.<nowiki><ref></nowiki>[[English Wikipedia]] AfD for "Summability Criterion": https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Wikipedia:Articles_for_deletion/Summability_criterion
 
Line 27 ⟶ 34:
Strictly speaking, a method is kth-order summable if an election involving <math>V</math> voters and <math>c</math> candidates can be stored in a data structure (a summary) that requires <math>O(\log(V) \cdot c^k)</math> bits in total, where there exists a summation operator that takes any two such summaries and produces a third for the combined election, and the election method itself can use these summaries instead of ballot sets to produce the same results. This definition closes the obvious loophole of using a few very large numbers to store more data than would otherwise be permitted.
 
== Summability of various voting methods==
 
{| class="wikitable" align="center" |border="1"
Line 45 ⟶ 52:
*the [[Contingent vote]]
*Borda-elimination ([[Baldwin's method|Baldwin]]<ref>{{Cite journal|last=Hogben|first=G.|date=1913|title=Preferential Voting in Single-member Constituencies, with Special Reference to the Counting of Votes|url=http://rsnz.natlib.govt.nz/volume/rsnz_46/rsnz_46_00_005780.html|journal=Transactions and Proceedings of the Royal Society of New Zealand|series=|volume=46|issue=|pages=304–308|via=}}</ref> and [[Nanson's method|Nanson]]<ref name="sumNanson">{{Cite journal|last=Nanson|first=E. J.|date=1882|title=Methods of election|url=https://archive.org/details/transactionsproc1719roya/page/197|journal=Transactions and Proceedings of the Royal Society of Victoria|volume=19|pages=197–240|via=}}</ref>)
* [[Bucklin voting|Bucklin]]
*[[Majority Judgment]]
*[[MCA|MCA-IR]], and some forms of [[MCA|MCA-AR]]
*[[STAR voting]]<ref>{{Cite news|title=Compare STAR and IRV - Equal Vote Coalition|url=https://www.equal.vote/star-vs-irv#simplicity|work=Equal Vote Coalition|access-date=2018-11-12}}</ref>
||
*[[Adjusted Condorcet Plurality]]
* [[Correlated Instant Borda Runoff]]
||
*[[Benham's method]]
Line 61 ⟶ 68:
==Examples==
 
=== Summable methods===
 
==== Points-scoring methods ====
 
=====Positional methods=====
Line 79 ⟶ 86:
For example, with [[Score voting]], a voter who votes A:10 B:6 C:3 D:1 is treated as giving a 10 to A, a 6 to B, etc. Comparisons across different score scales can be made by dividing the score by the max score (i.e. instead of a 6, treat it as a 6/10=0.6, etc.) so that a voter who scores a candidate a 3 out of 5 and a voter who scores a candidate a 6 out of 10 can have their scores treated and counted the same without any issues.
 
==== Pairwise methods====
{{Main|Pairwise counting}}
Some voting methods, such as [[STAR voting]] are precinct-summable using voter's pairwise preference order alongside the total score received for each candidate.
 
===== Condorcet methods=====
 
In [[Schulze method|Schulze]] and many other summable [[Condorcet method|Condorcet methods]], each vote is equivalent to a two-dimensional array referred to as a pairwise matrix. If candidate A is ranked above candidate B, then the element in the A row and B column gets a 1, while the element in the B row and A column gets a 0. The pairwise matrices for all the votes are summed, and the winner is determined from the resulting pairwise matrix sum. The precincts' matrices may be added together to get the matrix for the whole electorate, just like a precinct's voters' matrices may be added together to get the matrix for that precinct.
Line 91 ⟶ 98:
|+
!
! A
!B
!C
! D
|-
| A
| ---
| '''(A>B)''' 1
|1
|1
|-
|B
| '''(B>A)''' 0
| ---
| 0
|1
|-
|C
|0
| 0
| ---
|1
|-
| D
|0
|0
Line 135 ⟶ 142:
Suppose, for example, that the number of candidates is ten.
 
* Under first-order summable methods like [[plurality voting|plurality]] or [[Approval voting]], the votes at any level (precinct, ward, county, etc.) can be compressed into a list of ten numbers.
*For [[Schulze method|Schulze]], a 10×10 matrix is needed (although only 10x9=90 data values are actually kept).
*In an [[IRV]] system, however, each precinct would need to send a list of ten numbers, the number of first-place votes for each candidate. The central system would then return to each precinct a candidate to eliminate. Each precinct would then return the first-place votes for each of the nine remaining candidates, and receive another candidate to eliminate. This would be repeated at most 9 times. This is more than the others.
Line 147 ⟶ 154:
In first-order summable election systems, adding new ballots to the count (say, ballots that were found after the initial count, or late absentee ballots, or ballots that were initially ruled invalid) is as simple as "summing" the original result with the newly-found ballots. Under non-summable systems, though, finding new ballots means all ballots might possibly need to be recounted. This is not a big problem for computer recounts, but manual recounts can be extremely time-consuming and expensive.
 
== Multi-winner generalizations and results==
 
=== Generalized criteria ===
 
There's no one extension of the summability criterion for multiple winners, because the summability criterion only considers two variables (the number of voters and the number of candidates), whereas there's one more variable for a multi-winner method: the number of seats. One possible extension of the summability criterion is as follows:<ref>{{cite web|url=http://lists.electorama.com/pipermail/election-methods-electorama.com/2011-July/092996.html|title=Weighted voting systems for proportional representation|website=Election-methods mailing list archives|date=2011-07-24|last=Munsterhjelm|first=K.}}</ref>
 
* '''Weak summability''': Suppose that the number of seats is fixed. Then the method should be summable in terms of the number of candidates and the logarithm of the number of voters, as a single-winner method is. However, the amount of information required may increase exponentially with the number of seats.
 
* '''Strong summability''': There must exist a summary that passes summability (i.e. <math>O(\log(V) \cdot c^k)</math> bits in total) which can, after being compiled, be used to determine the outcome for the multi-winner method for ''any'' number of seats.
 
=== Results ===
 
Unless otherwise specified, these results pertain to strong summability.
Line 165 ⟶ 172:
Most [[block voting]] methods that are based on summable single-winner methods are also of the same degree of summability in the multi-winner case, and strongly so.
 
Generally speaking, except for proportional [[:Category:FPTP-based voting methods|Category:FPTP-based voting methods]] (which notably include [[Party list]] and [[SNTV]]), there are no seriously used summable [[:Category:PSC-compliant voting methods|Category:PSC-compliant voting methods]].
 
[[Ebert's method]] is summable in <math>O(c^2)</math> for any number of seats.<ref>{{cite web | title=proof that sum of squared loads is precinct-summable | date=2020-01-14 | url=https://forum.electionscience.org/t/possible-improvement-to-pamsac-gets-rid-of-cfat/566/19 | access-date=2020-04-29}}</ref>
Line 181 ⟶ 188:
Summability focuses on the amount of data that has to be captured, but not necessarily the amount of work required to capture it. For example, when doing [[pairwise counting]], an election featuring a ballot that ranks a candidate last requires as many marks to count as if the same ballot had been cast without the last-ranked candidate. Yet in practice, the vote-counters must still take some time to check that that candidate is indeed last-ranked, meaning some work is done even while no data was produced.
 
===Number of data value types versus number of data values ===
Summability focuses to a large extent on the number of data value types, not just the amount of data overall that has to be captured. This can make a difference in certain cases; for example, the regular [[pairwise counting]] approach only requires <math>n^2-n</math> data value types to be captured for all ballots, whereas the [[Negative vote-counting approach for pairwise counting]] requires <math>n^2</math> value types. This is because the latter not only records preferences in each pairwise matchup, but also the number of ballots ranking each candidate. Yet, depending on implementation, the negative counting approach actually has the same upper bound on number of data values to capture as the regular approach, and in practice could require fewer.
 
Line 198 ⟶ 205:
Most sequential [[Cardinal PR]] require less two-way communication and/or centralized counting work than most other [[PR]] methods.
 
==See also==
 
*[[Voting system]]
* [[Monotonicity criterion]]
*[[Condorcet Criterion]]
*[[Generalized Condorcet criterion]]
Line 207 ⟶ 214:
*[[Participation criterion]]
 
== References ==
<references />
 
==See also==
 
*[[Voting system]]
*[[Monotonicity criterion]]
*[[Condorcet Criterion]]