Algorithmic Asset Voting: Difference between revisions

Content added Content deleted
(Moved much of the relevant pieces from the main Asset Voting article to this article.)
(Added section on how an inventor of Asset, Lewis Carroll, likely believed Asset was the most Condorcet-efficient PR method of his time.)
Line 29: Line 29:


All 3 candidates are in a Condorcet cycle. Schulze picks C, so that would be the default outcome if no negotiation occurs. Based off of this, the algorithm can flip the 4 A>B>C voters to B>A>C to help resolve the cycle and elect B (since B would then be the only member of the Smith Set, B can't be overtaken by anyone else), because this change in expressed preference benefits these voters' actual preferences. Then, not enough C voters would have an incentive to negotiate to elect someone other than B. It may be possible for some cycles to only be resolvable when certain cycle resolution methods are used as default methods in Algorithmic Asset and not others.     
All 3 candidates are in a Condorcet cycle. Schulze picks C, so that would be the default outcome if no negotiation occurs. Based off of this, the algorithm can flip the 4 A>B>C voters to B>A>C to help resolve the cycle and elect B (since B would then be the only member of the Smith Set, B can't be overtaken by anyone else), because this change in expressed preference benefits these voters' actual preferences. Then, not enough C voters would have an incentive to negotiate to elect someone other than B. It may be possible for some cycles to only be resolvable when certain cycle resolution methods are used as default methods in Algorithmic Asset and not others.     

<br />

== Lewis Carroll's own likely observations that Asset is intended to be Condorcet-efficient ==
Lewis Carroll is the first known inventor of Asset Voting. In a passage in an article<ref>[https://www.rangevoting.org/BlackCarrollAER2.pdf]</ref> describing his thought process in developing Asset (starting at the sentence "Suppose we have a multimember constituency..." on Page 4 and ending at the sentence "In general, however, an operational answer to the problem is again not feasible." on Page 5), Carroll appears to have noted that the ideal PR scheme would involve voters forming into sets of coalitions, and then, when enough voters prefer a different set of coalitions than the one that is currently formed, a different set of coalitions is formed, and this repeats until no more improvement is possible. He also notes that it is possible to, by looking at ranked ballots, figure out what sets of coalitions might occur if the voters were acting "rationally" (most likely meaning maximally strategically), and he even solves a few examples where such an approach yields different results from STV, though it is noted that at the time, the full computation for this process when looking at the ballots for a large-scale election would've been "indeterminate". This all appears to establish that Carroll was interested in finding a Condorcet equilibrium for the final set of winners, and saw Asset as the easiest way to do it, because he believed the candidates' preferences would be close enough to the voters' preferences to make the candidates' Condorcet equilibrium more Condorcet-efficient by voter preference standards than STV.