Asset voting: Difference between revisions

Linking to w:Proxy voting on English Wikipedia
mNo edit summary
(Linking to w:Proxy voting on English Wikipedia)
 
(26 intermediate revisions by 5 users not shown)
Line 1:
{{Wikipedia|Proxy voting}}
'''Asset voting''' is used to refer to a voting system in which votes are considered as "assets" given to candidates. If no candidate gets more than the winning threshold (i.e., a majority, in the [[Single-winner voting system|single winner]] case; generally speaking, a [[Droop quota|Droop]] or Hare Quota), then the candidates can redistribute "their" votes to other candidates until a winner exists. Variations exist with different constraints on transfers - for example, the candidate with the fewest votes might be forced to redistribute their votes first. It is possible to force the negotiations to go on until there are enough candidates with quotas (say, Droop
 
Asset voting was invented in 1874 by [[w:Lewis Caroll|Lewis Caroll]] (Charles Dodgson), and independently reinvented and named by Forest Simmons and Warren Smith.<ref>{{Cite web|url=https://www.rangevoting.org/AssetCLD.html|title=Asset voting was invented by Lewis Carroll (Charles L. Dodgson)!|website=RangeVoting.org|access-date=2019-03-02}}</ref><ref>[{{Cite journal|url=http://www.rangevoting.org/BlackCarrollAER2.pdf |first=Duncan |last=Black: |title=Lewis Carroll and the Theory of Games, |journal=The American Economic Review |volume=59,|issue=2 (|date=May 1969) |pp=206-210]}}</ref>
Quo)tas to fill all (or all but one of the) seats, which in the single-winner case would, under the former condition, mean requiring the winner to earn a majority of assets.
 
If used as a [[Voting systems#MultipleMulti-winnerMember methodsSystem|multi-winner voting method]], it obeys most [[PSC|proportionality criteria]], if the requisite assumptions about coalitions are extended to include candidates as well as voters. For example, since Asset allows a negotiator or group of negotiators who hold a certain number of Droop Quotas of votes to guarantee the election of up to that number of their preferred candidates (see [[SNTV]]), if the negotiators follow voter preferences then proportionality for Droop solid coalitions is satisfied. In such use, it is similar to [[delegable proxy]] systems except that, unlike such systems, it has public elections only at regularly scheduled intervals (proxies are not "revocable") and elects a fixed number of representatives with equal power.
Asset voting was invented in 1874 by [[Lewis Caroll]] (Charles Dodgson), and independently reinvented and named by Forest Simmons and Warren Smith.<ref>{{Cite web|url=https://www.rangevoting.org/AssetCLD.html|title=Asset voting was invented by Lewis Carroll (Charles L. Dodgson)!|website=RangeVoting.org|access-date=2019-03-02}}</ref><ref>[http://www.rangevoting.org/BlackCarrollAER2.pdf Duncan Black: Lewis Carroll and the Theory of Games, The American Economic Review 59,2 (May 1969) 206-210]</ref>
 
Note that several assumptions are made throughout the article to make Asset comparable to other [[voting method]]<nowiki/>s; specifically, sometimes Asset is discussed as if the voters themselves are trading votes. In practice however, Asset could fail just about every criterion and yield any type of election result.
If used as a [[Voting systems#Multiple-winner methods|multi-winner voting method]], it obeys most [[proportionality criteria]], if the requisite assumptions about coalitions are extended to include candidates as well as voters. In such use, it is similar to [[delegable proxy]] systems except that, unlike such systems, it has public elections only at regularly scheduled intervals (proxies are not "revocable") and elects a fixed number of representatives with equal power.
 
== Connection to other voting methods ==
Asset is Droop-proportional based on negotiator preferences (which can diverge from voter preferences), meaning that if a negotiator or group of negotiators hold a certain number of Droop Quotas of votes, they can guarantee the election of up to that number of their preferred candidates. Further, Asset always picks a winner or winner set that is in the [[Smith set|Smith Set]] based on negotiators' preferences (which is not necessarily the same as the voters' preferences, since the negotiators may be corrupt, change preferences mid-negotiation, not know the voters' full preferences, etc.) if the negotiators are given enough time to negotiate and are honest with each other in their negotiating moves,{{Dubious|date=2019-12}} meaning that if the negotiators have discussed every relevant permutation of winners or winner sets, Asset will always produce an outcome that can earn more votes during the negotiations than any other possible outcome, unless certain outcomes earn more votes than each other in a [[Condorcet paradox|Condorcet cycle]]. In the single-winner case, if the negotiators are honest, strictly follow voter preferences, and have enough time to negotiate, then Asset becomes a Smith-efficient [[Condorcet method]], and in the multiwinner case, resembles Condorcet PR methods such as [[CPO-STV]] and [[Schulze STV]].
 
=== Connection to Condorcet ===
Asset can, under ideal conditions in the multiwinner case, render many if not all free-riding strategies needless; this is because, in some sense, the negotiators can do vote management themselves. Consider the example of three parties, A, B and C, where 51 voters vote for B candidates, 49 vote for A candidates, and 10 for C candidates, and there are 5 seats to be elected. Supposing every voter gives maximal support to all of the candidates of their chosen party, and no support for any other candidate, Party B will win 3 seats in most PR methods. However, if the 49 A voters divide themselves as evenly as possible between 3 of their candidates (17 of them bullet vote the first, 16 each bullet vote the second and third candidates), and a Droop quota is spent every time someone is elected in the PR method, then Party A will be able to win 3 seats instead. With Asset, the B candidates can agree to divide their 51 votes evenly between 3 of them (17 each), ensuring that their candidates will be 3 of the 5 candidates with the most votes when the negotiations end and thus win. <ref>[https://forum.electionscience.org/t/different-reweighting-for-rrv-and-the-concept-of-vote-unitarity/201/92]</ref>
Asset is Droop-proportional based on negotiator preferences (which can diverge from voter preferences), meaning that if a negotiator or group of negotiators hold a certain number of Droop Quotas of votes, they can guarantee the election of up to that number of their preferred candidates. Further, Asset always picks a winner or winner set that is in the [[Smith set|Smith Set]] based on negotiators' preferences (which is not necessarily the same as the voters' preferences, since the negotiators may be corrupt, change preferences mid-negotiation, not know the voters' full preferences, etc.) if the negotiators are given enough time to negotiate and, are honest with each other in their negotiating moves, don't attempt to strategically alter their preferences,{{Dubious|date=2019-12}} and if each candidate in the Smith set is preferred by at least a [[Droop quota]] of all voters in every pairwise comparison, meaning that if the negotiators have discussed every relevant permutation of winners or winner sets, Asset will always produce an outcome that can earn more votes from the negotiators during the negotiations than any other possible outcome, unless certain outcomes earn more votes than each other in a [[Condorcet paradox|Condorcet cycle]]. In the single-winner case, if the negotiators are honest, strictly follow voter preferences, and have enough time to negotiate, then Asset becomes a Smith-efficient [[Condorcet method]], and in the multiwinnerwhich case, resemblesone Condorcetof PRthose methodscycling suchoutcomes aswill [[CPO-STV]]win. and [[Schulze STV]].
 
Example: <blockquote>3: A>B>C
Sequential Asset Voting can be done by doing Asset sequentially in the multiwinner case: multiple rounds of negotiations are done, and after each round, the candidate(s) with the most votes are elected. If only one candidate is elected at a time, this can allow a majority to win every seat, and could be considered Bloc Asset Voting, as this is akin to deterministic Bloc methods such as Bloc Approval Voting. It is also possible to spend or exhaust some votes after each seat is elected, which can influence the negotiation and potentially make Sequential Asset move in a continuum between majoritarianism and proportionality. If a Droop quota of votes is spent each time, for example, then Sequential Asset becomes at least semi-proportional based on negotiator preferences.
 
.3: B>C>A
 
3: C>A>B
 
4: D </blockquote>D starts out with the most votes in the negotiation, but the ABC bloc is a [[mutual majority]], so they have an incentive to put their 9 votes behind one of ABC because they prefer any of them to D winning. In general, the idea is that because Smith candidates [[pairwise beat]] non-Smith candidates, this means that by definition more voters have an incentive to elect Smith candidates than non-Smith candidates. This has interesting extensions to the PR case (see [[Condorcet PR]]), because voters must sometimes keep their vote with a favorite candidate to make their favorite win, preventing them from also supporting their 2nd choice to beat their 3rd choice.
 
==== Contrast with IRV ====
<blockquote>46 A>B
 
10 B
 
44 C>B </blockquote>A starts out with the most votes in the negotiations, but C-top voters can end that by giving their 44 votes to B, making B have more votes (54 total). A-top voters can't do anything to stop B from winning, C-top voters have no ability to elect C, and prefer B over A, and B-top voters are getting their 1st choice, so no voters have both incentive and ability to change the outcome, and so B would win. This is an example of the negotiation process averting the [[center squeeze effect]] and electing the [[Condorcet winner]].
 
Note that in [[IRV]], once B was eliminated, C would have a majority of votes; the 56 voters who prefer B to C wouldn't be able to overpower the 44 that prefer C by transferring their votes toward B.
 
==== Majority-beat constraint ====
However, this doesn't apply when some candidates in the Smith set don't have at least a Droop quota of all voters preferring them in some comparisons; example:
 
25 A>B
 
26 B>A
 
3 C>A
 
46 C
 
A is the CW. However, C starts out with the most votes; if a B vs C matchup is done first, then B will beat C, and then if an A vs B matchup is done, if the A-top voters try to make A win, then C will have the most votes (more than A or B), whereas if they continue to support B (as they did during the B vs C match-up), they ensure B wins. So in this circumstance, because A wasn't a [[Majority Condorcet winner]] (A got 28 votes against B's 26, but this is less than a majority of all voters, which is 51), the [[chicken dilemma]] allowed B to win.
 
=== Connection to utilitarianism ===
Because the [[utilitarian winner]] can be thought of as a "weighted" [[Condorcet winner]], if the negotiators only use parts of their votes (like [[cumulative voting]]) to support their preferred candidates, then Asset may begin to resemble a [[Cardinal PR]] method. Single-winner example:<blockquote>51 A:5 B:4 49 B:5</blockquote>If the max score is 5, then A 100% supports himself and 80% supports B. In general, to solve these situations, each voter should only give to their favorite candidate as much of their vote as their strength of preference for them i.e. someone who only 80% supports their favorite and 60% supports their second choice gives their favorite 80% of a vote, leaving 20% unusable. Then, to determine how the votes are transferred in head-to-head matchups, you find the fraction for the support for the less-preferred candidate divided by the support for the more-preferred candidate, and divide this by 2; this is the fraction of the more-preferred candidate's votes you transfer to the less-preferred candidate for that voter. This will replicate the utility margin between the two candidates. So here, for the 51 voters, the fraction is 80/100=(4/5)/2=2/5 so they transfer 2/5ths of their votes for A to B. The 49 B voters' fraction is 0/100 i.e. they don't support A at all, so they don't give any of their votes for B to A. So the final vote total is A 30.6 B 69.4, creating a vote margin of 38.8 in favor of B. This replicates the utility margin, which was A 51 subtracted from B (49 + 51*0.8)=89.8, which is 38.8.
 
This example is somewhat farcical, but in general, [[utilitarianism]] can be viewed through an Asset lens as negotiators only weakly pushing for some preferences. Asset may even be modelable as one of the cardinal PR methods when all negotiators' preferences are cardinal and not ranked. Also see the [[utility]] article for discussion on the connection between majority rule and utilitarianism. It is also worth looking into how negotiators can have weak preferences in some pairwise matchups but strong preferences in others, which all together could not be written on a rated ballot as a rated utility; see [[Rated pairwise preference ballot]] for discussion on this. 
 
== Free-riding ==
Asset can, under ideal conditions in the multiwinner case, render many if not all[[Free riding|free-riding]] strategies needless; this is because, in some sense, the negotiators can do vote management themselves. Consider the example of three parties, A, B and C, where 51 voters vote for B candidates, 49 vote for A candidates, and 10 for C candidates, and there are 5 seats to be elected. Supposing every voter gives maximal support to all of the candidates of their chosen party, and no support for any other candidate, Party B will win 3 seats in most PR methods. However, if the 49 A voters divide themselves as evenly as possible between 3 of their candidates (17 of them bullet vote the first, 16 each bullet vote the second and third candidates), and a Droop quota is spent every time someone is elected in the PR method, then Party A will be able to win 3 seats instead. With Asset, the B candidates can agree to divide their 51 votes evenly between 3 of them (17 each), ensuring that their candidates will be 3 of the 5 candidates with the most votes when the negotiations end and thus win. <ref name="The Center for Election Science 2019">[{{cite web | title=Different reweighting for RRV and the concept of Vote Unitarity | website=The Center for Election Science | date=2019-06-29 | url=https://forum.electionscience.org/t/different-reweighting-for-rrv-and-the-concept-of-vote-unitarity/201/92] | access-date=2020-02-19}}</ref>
 
Note however that free riding still can work if a voter honestly supports both a candidate with a small base and a candidate with the same small base combined with other bases, as the voter may wish to give their vote to the first candidate to elect them and hope the other bases will elect the second candidate, giving the voter two rather than only one of their preferred candidates. This type of free riding can lead to popular candidates losing to candidates equally preferred to them by smaller groups of voters if too many voters attempt it.
 
== Variations ==
Variations exist with different constraints on transfers - for example, the candidate with the fewest votes might be forced to redistribute their votes first. There need not be any threshold either i.e. for however many seats there are to be filled, for that number of candidates with the most votes, they are elected. This variation means that, in this single-winner example: <blockquote>51 A
 
49 B
 
10 C </blockquote>Candidate C can't prevent A from winning by denying them a Droop quota, since A has the most votes overall.
 
== Extensions ==
Asset Voting also has [[Sequential Asset Voting|sequential]] and Bloc versions of itself, which are generally less proportional and more majoritarian than regular Asset in the multiwinner cases (with Bloc Asset, a majority can win every seat). All of these various forms of Asset Voting can be [[Algorithmic Asset Voting|algorithmized]], and under certain (relevant) assumptions, become some type of Condorcet or Condorcet PR method.
 
== Notes ==
Asset voting's [[party list case]] is [[D'Hondt]]. This is because negotiators can always split votes per seat in an optimal fashion to get as many seats as they'd get in D'Hondt.
 
=== Independence properties ===
Asset passes [[Independence of Smith-dominated Alternatives]], because once the negotiators start discussing electing Smith set members, they won't be able to form a coalition in favor of a non-Smith candidate, and any Smith candidate is likely to be viable since there is a [[beat-or-tie path]] between all of them.
 
Under certain assumptions, Asset passes [[Pareto efficiency|Independence of Pareto-dominated alternatives]]. This is because the Pareto-dominating alternative will [[pairwise beat]] the Pareto-dominated alternative, and there is no incentive for any negotiator to elect the Pareto-dominated alternative instead of the Pareto candidate. So the negotiators would have an incentive to discard consideration of any Pareto-dominated alternatives.
 
=== Presentation ===
Asset negotiations can be modeled similarly to [[IRV]] i.e. every round, the number of votes pledged or offered to each candidate are counted. With such a presentation, it would then be shown who would win in a given round if that was the final round. This can be used to explain why the negotiators shifted their votes in a later round. In this sense, Asset, and by extension, [[Condorcet]] or [[Condorcet PR]], can be thought of as superior to [[STV]] because it allows voters to get a better deal for themselves by pivoting back towards candidates who seemed unattractive in earlier rounds but are found to be more viable than the voter's favorite, whereas STV just eliminates such candidates.
 
== References ==
<references />
[[Category:Single-mark ballot voting methods]]
[[Category:Multi-winner voting methods]]
[[Category:Single-winner voting methods]]
[[Category:FPTP-based voting methods]]
[[Category:Delegated voting methods]]