Distributed Score Voting: Difference between revisions

no edit summary
m (Criteria table added)
No edit summary
 
(14 intermediate revisions by 4 users not shown)
Line 1:
Distributed Score Voting (DSV) is a [[Single Member system|Single-Winner]] and [[Multi-Member System|Multi-Winner]] [[Cardinal voting systems| Cardinal voting system]].
 
In the [[Single Member system|Single-Winner]] part, it's similar to [[Smith//Score]]. In the [[Multi-Member System|Multi-Winner]] part, [[Distributed Multi-Voting]], the more preferred the winning candidate is in a vote, the more the weight of that vote is decreased in the choice of the next winner.
 
[[Category:Multi-winner voting methods]]
Line 7 ⟶ 9:
 
==Procedure==
[[File:DVS counting.jpg|alt=|thumb|DSV counting]]
 
===Voting===
Each voter has 100 points to distribute among the candidates according to his preferences (it's also possible to write the vote even in a simpler form, with range from 0 to 5 points for each candidate).
 
All candidates in the vote have 0 points by default.
[[File:DVSDSV countingprocedure.jpg|alt=|thumb|DSV counting]]
 
===Counting the votes===
W = sum of all the points in the original vote (100 for all votersvotes, at the beginning).
 
1) All head-to-head matches are conducted between candidates. In head-to-head, the candidate who has more points in a vote than his opponent receives W points from the vote. The candidate who gets the most points wins the head-to-head.
Line 23 ⟶ 24:
2) Find the smallest set X ([[Smith set]]) of nodes that don’t have incoming arrows, coming from outside the set.
 
3) Convert the votes using the following formula:
Then remove all candidates not in X from the votes.
 
3) Convert the votes into a range form, assigning 0 points to the candidates with the lowest score and normalizing the remaining candidates, using the following formula:
 
M = highest score among the candidates in the vote, before normalization.
Line 37 ⟶ 36:
v1=\frac{v0}{M} \cdot W
\end{equation}</math>
 
Then remove all candidates not in X from the votes.
 
4) Add up the points for each candidate of the range votes, and the candidate who has the highest sum, wins.
Line 46 ⟶ 47:
The value W of each original vote changes according to the following formula:
 
M = highest score among the candidates in the vote (before removing the candidate).
 
e = candidate's score eliminated.
Line 56 ⟶ 57:
<math>
\begin{equation}
W1=\frac{W0+100}{\left( 1-+\frac{e}{M}\right)}
\end{equation}</math>
 
(the formula shown above is temporary and may be subject to change)
 
By repeating this process several times, you can get as many winners as you like, which will be those removed in point 5.
Line 99 ⟶ 98:
Before the counting process, the votes will be normalized to 100-point votes, where the Xs are considered as equal weight values.
 
Examples of how a vote can be written by the voter and subsequently, inbefore the counting, converted into 100 points:
 
X,0,0,0,0 → 100,0,0,0,0
Line 126 ⟶ 125:
! rowspan=1 | [[Smith criterion|Smith]]
! rowspan=1 | [[Pareto criterion|Pareto]]
! rowspan=1 | IIA*
! rowspan=1 | [[Independence of irrelevant alternatives|IIA]]
! rowspan=1 | [[w:Independence of clones criterion|Clone proof]]
Line 139:
|-
! [[Distributed_Score_Voting|DSV<br>single-winner]]
! style="background: #98ff98; font-weight: inherit;" | Yes
! style="background: #98ff98; font-weight: inherit;" | Yes
! style="background: #98ff98; font-weight: inherit;" | Yes
! style="background: #98ff98; font-weight: inherit;" | Yes
Line 152 ⟶ 150:
! style="background: #98ff98; font-weight: inherit;" | Yes
! style="background: #98ff98; font-weight: inherit;" | Yes
! style="background: #98ff98fd8787; font-weight: inherit;" | YesNo
! style="background: #fd8787; font-weight: inherit;" | No
! style="background: #98ff98; font-weight: inherit;" | Yes
! style="background: #98ff98fd8787; font-weight: inherit;" | YesNo
! style="background: #fd8787; font-weight: inherit;" | No
|}
 
<b>IIA*</b>: X is a set containing all the preferred candidates over B. If I add C a less appreciated candidate (in head-to-head) than the candidates in X, then all candidates in X continue to be preferred over B.
[[Consistency criterion|Consistency]] is not satisfied because [[Distributed Score Voting|DSV]] wants to guarantee the victory of the candidate who wins in all heads-to-head matches.
 
This method also passes [[ISDA]].
[[Later-no-help criterion|Later-no-Help]] isn't satisfied because [[Distributed Score Voting|DSV]] wants to guarantee the defeat of candidates who aren't in the Smith set. This can generate tactical votes, described below.
 
All the criteria not met are linked to the fact that, through tactical votes, it's possible add / remove a candidate from the [[Smith set]].
 
- add one more candidate into the [[Smith set]] isn't a big problem because that additional candidate must then beat all the other candidates in point 4 of the procedure (and if he manages to beat them all it makes sense that he wins).
 
- removing a candidate from the [[Smith set]] is only possible when that candidate lose all the head-to-head with the candidates contained in the [[Smith set]]. This actually becomes a problem only if the excluded candidate is the one who really should have won.
 
Below is an example in which, through tactical votes, it's possible to bring out a candidate, who should have won, from the [[Smith set]] (making him lose).
 
===Tactical votes===
Line 173 ⟶ 182:
* the new winner is actually a better candidate than the previous one (the new winner in the example could also be C).
* the voter has a fairly precise knowledge of the likely ballots result, without which this tactical vote would turn against him.
 
[[Category:Smith-efficient Condorcet methods]]