House monotonicity criterion: Difference between revisions

Content added Content deleted
No edit summary
(Undo revision 9155 by Dr. Edmonds (talk))
Tag: Undo
Line 1: Line 1:
The '''House monotonicity criterion''' is a criterion for apportionment/party list methods, and by extension, for multi-member methods in general. The term was first used by Balinski and Young in 1974.<ref name="Balinski Young pp. 4602–4606">{{cite journal | last=Balinski | first=M. L. | last2=Young | first2=H. P. | title=A New Method for Congressional Apportionment | journal=Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences | publisher=Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences | volume=71 | issue=11 | date=1974-11-01 | issn=0027-8424 | doi=10.1073/pnas.71.11.4602 | pages=4602–4606}}</ref>
The '''House monotonicity criterion''' is a criterion for apportionment/party list methods, and by extension, for multi-member methods in general. The term was first used by Balinski and Young in 1974.<ref name="Balinski Young pp. 4602–4606">{{cite journal | last=Balinski | first=M. L. | last2=Young | first2=H. P. | title=A New Method for Congressional Apportionment | journal=Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences | publisher=Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences | volume=71 | issue=11 | date=1974-11-01 | issn=0027-8424 | doi=10.1073/pnas.71.11.4602 | pages=4602–4606}}</ref>


The house monotonicity criterion for a [[Party list]] method is:
The house monotonicity criterion for an apportionment method is:


{{Definition| If the number of seats increases with fixed populations, then no party can have its number of seats decrease.}}
{{Definition| If the number of seats increases with fixed populations, no state delegation decreases.}}


That is, a state must never lose a seat from the number of total seats increasing. The [[Alabama paradox]] is an example of a house monotonicity failure.
That is, a state must never lose a seat from the number of total seats increasing. When used as a [[party list]] system, no party can lose a seat in this way, either. The [[Alabama paradox]] is an example of a house monotonicity failure.


By extension, the house monotonicity criterion for a [[Multi-Member System]] is:<ref name="Woodall 1994 Properties">{{cite journal | last=Woodall |first=D. |title=Properties of preferential election rules | journal=Voting matters | issue=3 | pages=8–15 | year=1994 | url=http://www.votingmatters.org.uk/ISSUE3/P5.HTM}}</ref>
By extension, the house monotonicity criterion for a [[multi-member system]] is:<ref name="Woodall 1994 Properties">{{cite journal | last=Woodall |first=D. |title=Properties of preferential election rules | journal=Voting matters | issue=3 | pages=8–15 | year=1994 | url=http://www.votingmatters.org.uk/ISSUE3/P5.HTM}}</ref>


{{Definition|If only the seat count is increase then the [[Winner set]] must include all prior winners }}
{{Definition|No candidate should be harmed by an increase in the number of seats to be filled, with no change to the profile.}}

That is, increasing the number of winners should never evict anyone from the [[winner set]] who is already in it.


House monotone multi-member methods are sometimes called proportional orderings or proportional rankings<ref>{{cite web|url=http://9mail-de.spdns.de/m-schulze/schulze2.pdf|title=Free Riding and Vote Management under Proportional Representation by the Single Transferable Vote|date=2011-03-14|author=Markus Schulze|page=42}}</ref>, and James Green-Armytage's [[Proportional Ordering]] is such a method. Sequential methods without deletion steps, such as [[sequential Ebert]] and [[Sequential Phragmen|sequential Phragmén]], are also house monotone.
House monotone multi-member methods are sometimes called proportional orderings or proportional rankings<ref>{{cite web|url=http://9mail-de.spdns.de/m-schulze/schulze2.pdf|title=Free Riding and Vote Management under Proportional Representation by the Single Transferable Vote|date=2011-03-14|author=Markus Schulze|page=42}}</ref>, and James Green-Armytage's [[Proportional Ordering]] is such a method. Sequential methods without deletion steps, such as [[sequential Ebert]] and [[Sequential Phragmen|sequential Phragmén]], are also house monotone.
Line 17: Line 19:
* [[Balinski–Young theorem]]
* [[Balinski–Young theorem]]
* [[Population monotonicity]]
* [[Population monotonicity]]

== References ==
== References ==