Preferential voting: Difference between revisions

Suggesting merge to Ranked voting article
(Category:Ballot types (not type))
(Suggesting merge to Ranked voting article)
 
(One intermediate revision by one other user not shown)
Line 1:
{{merge to|Ranked voting|date=August 2022}}
{{Wikipedia}}
 
Line 20 ⟶ 21:
(4) Often the term preferential voting is used for any kind of intraparty preference.{{Clarify|reason=|date=February 2020}}
 
Ballot design or voting machine instructions are particularly important in such systems, as each voter is expected to express a rather complex set of [[tolerances versus preferences|tolerances or preferences]] in each vote.
 
Example: if there are 4 candidates, A, B, C and D, then a voter could rank them as A>B>C=D (A is the voter's 1st choice, but they'll take B if they can't get A because B is their 2nd choice, and C and D are equally preferable), B>C (B is better than C), etc. When a voter doesn't rank all candidates, it's usually assumed they have no preference between the candidates they didn't rank, and that they prefer every candidate they ranked over all of their unranked candidates.
Line 43 ⟶ 44:
 
==Scope for corruption==
A potential problem with preferential votes is that they can be used to undermine a [[secret ballot]], and thus enable corruption by vote buying. If there are enough candidates then the number of possible voting patterns may be much larger than the number of voters, and it then becomes possible to use early preferences to vote for the desired candidates and then to use later preferences to identify the voter to the person who has purchased the vote and looks at the ballot papers.
 
As an example, in the Irish general election of 2002, the electronic votes were published for the Dublin North constituency. There were 17 candidates, allowing more than 966 million million possible patterns of preferences, but there were fewer than 44,000 votes cast. The most common pattern (for three of the candidates in a particular order) was chosen by 800 voters, and more than 16,000 patterns were chosen by just one voter each.
 
One way to avoid this possibility for buying a vote and confirming it has been cast as specified is to prevent partisan observers from systematically viewing individual voter's preferences. Another option is to, when publishing the ballots, truncate preferences that are voted by fewer voters than some threshold. For instance, if a hundred voters all voted A>B>C but then each of these voters ranked the remaining candidates in an unique order, only publish 100: A>B>C.
 
==How to Vote Cards and "Above the line" voting==
Line 53 ⟶ 54:
 
==Parliamentary procedure==
Recent editions of [[Robert's Rules of Order]] mention preferential voting. The book notes, "While it is more complicated than other methods of voting in common use and is not a substitute for the normal procedure of repeated balloting until a majority is obtained, preferential voting is especially fair and useful in an election by mail if it is impractical to take more than one ballot" (RONR [10th ed.], p. 411, l. 23). Rather than discuss Condorcet, the Borda count, and other lesser-known variations, the book simply states, "Preferential voting has many variations. One method is described here by way of illustration," and proceeds with a description of [[instant -runoff voting]].
 
== Notes ==