Proportional approval voting: Difference between revisions

no edit summary
(Undo revision 2194 by 199.164.125.138 (talk) per suggestion on the Center for Election Science Discord server)
Tag: Undo
No edit summary
 
(2 intermediate revisions by one other user not shown)
Line 1:
{{Wikipedia}}
 
'''Proportional approval voting''' (PAV) is a theoretical [[voting system]] for multiple-winner elections, in which each voter can vote for as many or as few candidates as the voter chooses. It was developed by the Danish polymath Thorvald N. Thiele, and its [[Sequential proportional approval voting|sequential approximation]] was used in Swedish elections up until its replacement by the less computationally laborious party-list system.<ref>{{cite web |url=http://www2.math.uu.se/~svante/papers/sjV6.pdf |title=Proportionella valmetoder |date=2012-08-20|last=Janson |first=Svante|journal=Typescript, Uppsala|access-date=2020-02-28}}</ref> andIt was thenlater rediscovered by Forest Simmons in 2001.<ref>{{cite web | title=Proportional Representation via Approval Voting | website=Election-methods mailing list archives | url=http://lists.electorama.com/pipermail/election-methods-electorama.com/2001-January/070294.html | access-date=2020-02-28 |date=2001-01-12 |first=Forest |last=Simmons}}</ref>
 
PAV works by looking at how "satisfied" each voter is with each potential result or outcome of the of the election.
Line 27:
 
The system disadvantages minority groups who share some preferences with the majority. In terms of [[tactical voting]], it is therefore highly desirable to withhold approval from candidates who are likely to be elected in any case, as with [[cumulative voting]] and the [[single non-transferable vote]].
 
PAV is strongly [[Monotonicity|monotonic]] and passes [[Independence of Irrelevant Ballots]] (IIB). However, it fails the [[Universally liked candidate criterion]] (ULC) and also [[Perfect representation|Perfect Representation In the Limit]] (PRIL), which is arguably a prerequisite for an approval method to be considered properly proportional.
 
== Example ==
Line 54 ⟶ 56:
== Similar Systems ==
 
Both the [[Phragmén's Method]] and [[w:Sequential_proportional_approval_voting|Sequential Proportional Approval Voting]] are very similar systems invented in the early 1900s. [[Reweighted Range Voting]] is thean extension of this concept to [[Score Voting]], along with [[Harmonic Voting]] and its sequential counterpart, [[Sequential proportional score voting]]. These systems all derive their reweighting theory as the natural extension of the [[Jefferson Method]] to [[Multi-Member System]]s.
 
Optimised PAV is the version of the method that allows any number of candidates to be elected according to the optimal candidate weights, rather than a fixed number with equal weight. It is not known if this method passes PRIL, but on the assumption that is does, it has been considered, along with [[COWPEA]], as a candidate method for the most accurately proportional approval method.<ref>{{Cite journal|last=Pereira|first=Toby|date=2023-05-17|title=COWPEA (Candidates Optimally Weighted in Proportional Election using Approval voting)|url=https://arxiv.org/abs/2305.08857|journal=arXiv}}</ref> Optimised PAV Lottery elects a fixed number of candidates with equal weight, using the candidate weights as probabilities, and it has parallels with COWPEA Lottery. If it does pass PRIL, then it would pass the four main Holy Grail criteria of PRIL, strong monotonicity, IIB and ULC, along with COWPEA Lottery.
 
== References ==