Ranked Robin: Difference between revisions

(→‎Example election: Forgot to change some “>”s to “=“s when I originally transferred over the ballot set.)
(I made a lot of big changes, almost exclusively simplifying.)
 
(10 intermediate revisions by 4 users not shown)
Line 1:
Ranked Robin is a [[Condorcet method|Condorcet voting method]] focused on the presentation of the results such that everyday voters can understand them without extensive education. Ranked Robin uses a [https://electowiki.org/wiki/Ballot#Ranked_ballot ranked ballot]. Voters are free to rank multiple candidates equally on their ballots. The candidate who winsbeats the most other candidates [[Pairwise preference#Definitions|head-to-head matchups against other candidates]] is elected, much like a [[w:round-robin tournament|round-robin tournament]].
 
== History ==
Line 8:
 
== Local counting ==
Ranked Robin is [[Precinct-summable|precinct summable]] through the use of [[Pairwise comparison matrix|preference matrices]]. Full preference matrices can be created simply by hand if needed and then reported directly to the media and the public, allowing ballots and ballot data to remain local for recounts and risk-limiting audits without risking the threat of [[w:Electoral fraud#Vote buying|vote selling]] and voter coercion<ref>See Ballotpedia's "[https://ballotpedia.org/Intimidation_of_voters Intimidation of voters]" article for more about voter coercion.</ref>. This decentralization of tallying allows elections to remain robust against scaled election attacks, which is vital in jurisdictions that run geographically-spread or high-profile elections. In contrast, voting methods that are not precinct summable, like [[Instant runoff voting|Ranked Choice (Instant Runoff) Voting]] and many expressive [[Proportional Representation|proportional voting methods]], lose these benefits and can lead to distrust in election outcomes if fraud, attacks, or even simple mistakes happen under a centralized counting authority.
 
== Tabulation ==
Line 73:
|—
|}
'''Ava''' pairwise beats the greatest number of candidates, '''3''', so she is elected as the winner.
 
== Tie-breaking mechanics ==
 
=== Frequency of ties ===
Almost all real-worldpublic elections using Ranked Robin will not have any ties for the winning candidate. However, ties under Ranked Robin may potentially be more common than ties under [[First Past the Post electoral system|Choose-one Voting]]. While there are 4 degrees of tiebreakers defined, ties after the '''1<sup>st</sup> Degree''' tiebreaker are about as rare as ties under Choose-one Voting, and ties after the '''2<sup>nd</sup> Degree''' tiebreaker are much rarer than that.
 
=== Degrees of ties ===
If there is a tie (including [[Condorcet paradox|Condorcet cycles]]), use the '''1<sup>st</sup> Degree''' tie-breaking method to resolve it. If there is still a tie, use the '''2<sup>nd</sup> Degree''' tiebreaker, and so on.
 
'''1<sup>st</sup> Degree:''' Declare the tied candidates finalists. Elect the finalist with the greatest sum of win [[margins]] over the other finalists.
'''1<sup>st</sup> Degree:''' Declare the tied candidates finalists. For each finalist, subtract the number of votes preferring each other finalist from the number of votes preferring them over each other finalist. The finalist with the greatest total difference is elected. For example, let <math>A_w</math> be the number of votes preferring finalist <math display="inline">A</math> over each other finalist (equivalent to the sum of the values in <math display="inline">A</math>'s row in a preference matrix consisting only of finalists) and let <math>A_l</math> be the number of votes preferring each other finalist over <math display="inline">A</math> (equivalent to the sum of the values in <math display="inline">A</math>'s column in a preference matrix consisting only of finalists); <math display="inline">A</math>'s total difference is <math>A_w-A_l</math>. This is mathematically equivalent to the [https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Borda_count#Tournament-style_counting_of_ties tournament-style of the Borda count] (among only the finalists), where candidates get, per ballot, 1 point for each candidate they beat and ½ point for each candidate they tie. There are two alternate, more concise ways of describing the '''1<sup>st</sup> Degree''' tiebreaker.
 
*To ''If there isfind a tie,win thenmargin for eacha tiedfinalist in a candidatematchup, subtract the number of votes preferringranking eachthe otheropponent tiedfinalist candidatehigher from the number of votes withranking the oppositefinalist preferencein question higher. ElectAdd thethese tiedmargins candidateup withfor theeach finalist to find their sum of win margins. Note that any of these values can be greatestpositive totalor differencenegative.''
* ''Among the candidates who tie for winning the most head-to-head matchups, elect the tied candidate with the best average rank.''
 
'''1<sup>st</sup>Since Degree:'''those Declaretwo thesteps tiedare candidatesboth finalists. For each finalistaddition, subtractthey thecan numberalso ofbe votescombined preferringinto each other finalist from the number of votes preferring them over each other finalist. The finalist with the greatest total difference isone electedstep. For example, let <math>A_w</math> be the number of votes preferring finalist <math display="inline">A</math> over each other finalist (equivalent to the sum of the values in <math display="inline">A</math>'s row in a preference matrix consistingthat consists only of finalists) and let <math>A_l</math> be the number of votes preferring each other finalist over <math display="inline">A</math> (equivalent to the sum of the values in <math display="inline">A</math>'s column in a preference matrix consistingthat consists only of finalists); <math display="inline">A</math>'s totalsum differenceof win margins is <math>A_w-A_l</math>. This is mathematically equivalent to the [https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Borda_count#Tournament-style_counting_of_ties tournament-style of the Borda count] (among only the finalists), where candidates get, per ballot, 1 point for each candidate they beat and ½ point for each candidate they tie. There are two alternate, more concise ways of describing the '''1<sup>st</sup> Degree''' tiebreaker.
'''2<sup>nd</sup> Degree:''' For each tied finalist, subtract the number of votes preferring each other candidate (including candidates who are not finalists) from the number of votes preferring them over each other candidate (including candidates who are not finalists). The tied finalist with the greatest total difference is elected.
 
'''2<sup>nd</sup> Degree:''' Elect the tied finalist with the greatest sum of win margins over ''all'' candidates.
'''3<sup>rd</sup> Degree:''' It is highly unlikely that there will still be a tie after the '''2<sup>nd</sup> Degree''' tiebreaker, but if there is, it is not recommended to use tie-breaking methods beyond the '''2<sup>nd</sup> Degree''' tiebreaker for government elections as voter trust may be shaken more by using the '''3<sup>rd</sup> Degree''' tiebreaker and beyond than drawing lots or hosting another election. In the event that there is a tie after the '''2<sup>nd</sup> Degree''' tiebreaker, the differences for the tied candidates will be the same, but the values used to calculate them will likely be different. Elect the tied candidate whose values are closest to the tied differences. For example, if <math display="inline">A</math>, <math display="inline">B
</math>, and <math display="inline">C</math> are tied after the '''2<sup>nd</sup> Degree''' tiebreaker, then <math>A_w-A_l=B_w-B_l=C_w-C_l</math> (where wins and loses are calculated across the entire field of candidates), but it's likely that <math>A_w\neq B_w\neq C_w</math> (and by proxy that <math>A_l\neq B_l\neq C_l</math>). The tied candidate with the greatest loss margin will also have the greatest win margin, and the tied candidate with the least loss margin will have the least win margin. Elect the tied candidate with the least loss and win margins as that is the least polarizing tied candidate.
 
'''3<sup>rd</sup> Degree:''' It is highly unlikely that there will still be a tie after the '''2<sup>nd</sup> Degree''' tiebreaker, but if there is, it is not recommended to use tie-breaking methods beyond the '''2<sup>nd</sup> Degree''' tiebreaker for governmentpublic elections as voter trust may be shaken more by using the '''3<sup>rd</sup> Degree''' tiebreaker and beyond than drawing lots or hosting another election. In the event that there is a tie after the '''2<sup>nd</sup> Degree''' tiebreaker, the differences for the tied candidates will be the same, but the values used to calculate them will likely be different. Elect the tied candidate whose values are closest to the tied differences. For example, if <math display="inline">A</math>, <math display="inline">B
'''4<sup>th</sup> Degree:''' If there is still a tie after the '''3<sup>rd</sup> Degree''' tiebreaker, it is unlikely that the '''4<sup>th</sup> Degree''' tiebreaker will break that tie, as it will only work if the tied candidates have matchup losses against other candidates. Find the shortest [[beatpath]] from each tied candidate to each other tied candidate. For each tied candidate, for each shortest beatpath to another tied candidate, for each pairwise victory in the beatpath, subtract the number of votes preferring the losing candidate from the number of votes preferring the winning candidate. Sum these differences within each selected beatpath to get the total strength of each selected beatpath. Sum each tied candidate's total beatpath strengths over other tied candidates. Elect the tied candidate with the greatest sum of beatpath strengths. If there are multiple shortest beatpaths from one tied candidate to another, select the one with the lowest total strength.
 
In the event that there is a tie after the '''2<sup>nd</sup> Degree''' tiebreaker, the sum of win margins for the tied candidates will be the same, but the values used to calculate them will likely be different. Elect the tied finalist whose values are closest to the tied margins.
 
For example, if <math display="inline">A</math>, <math display="inline">B
</math>, and <math display="inline">C</math> are tied after the '''2<sup>nd</sup> Degree''' tiebreaker, then <math>A_w-A_l=B_w-B_l=C_w-C_l</math> (where winswin and losesmargins are calculated across the entire field of candidates), but it's likely that <math>A_w\neq B_w\neq C_w</math> (and by proxy that <math>A_l\neq B_l\neq C_l</math>). The tied candidate with the greatest lossnumber marginof votes against them will also have the greatest winnumber of votes in favor of marginthem, and the tied candidate with the leastfewest number of votes lossagainst marginthem will have the leastfewest winnumber marginof votes for them. Elect the tied candidate with the leastfewest lossnumber andof winvotes marginson asboth metrics (for the motivation that isthey are the least polarizing tied candidate).
 
'''4<sup>th</sup> Degree:''' If there is still a tie after the '''3<sup>rd</sup> Degree''' tiebreaker, it is unlikely that the '''4<sup>th</sup> Degree''' tiebreaker will break that tie, as it will only work if the tied candidates have matchup losses against other candidates.
 
'''4<sup>th</sup> Degree:''' If there is still a tie after the '''3<sup>rd</sup> Degree''' tiebreaker, it is unlikely that the '''4<sup>th</sup> Degree''' tiebreaker will break that tie, as it will only work if the tied candidates have matchup losses against other candidates. Find the shortest [[beatpath]] from each tied candidate to each other tied candidate. For each tied candidate, for each shortest beatpath to another tied candidate, for each pairwise victory in the beatpath, subtractfind the numberwin of votes preferring the losing candidate from the number of votes preferring the winning candidatemargin. Sum these differenceswin margins within each selected beatpath to get the total strength of each selected beatpath. Sum each tied candidate's total beatpath strengths over other tied candidates. Elect the tied candidate with the greatest sum of beatpath strengths. (Every number in this calculation will be positive.) If there are multiple shortest beatpaths from one tied candidate to another, select the one with the lowest total strength.
 
==== Example of a ballot set that requires all 4 tie-breaking degrees ====
Line 117 ⟶ 124:
 
4: Ava>Bianca=Fabio
 
4: Ava=Bianca>Fabio
 
2: Bianca=Fabio>Ava=Eli}}Here's the preference matrix:
Line 136 ⟶ 145:
|'''39'''
|'''42'''
|'''5256'''
|'''188204'''
|-
|'''Bianca over'''
Line 145 ⟶ 154:
|''31''
|'''46'''
|'''4751'''
|'''188204'''
|-
|'''Cedric over'''
Line 163 ⟶ 172:
|—
|'''30'''
|'''38'''
|'''175'''
|-
Line 178 ⟶ 187:
|''16''
|''24''
|''3539''
|''35'39'''
|''2832''
|—
|'''138150'''
|-
|''Column total (votes against)''
|''149''
|''149''
|''169181''
|''156168''
|''178190''
|''224232''
|'''10251069''' - ''10251069'' = <u>0</u>
|}
'''Ranked Robin:''' Ava and Bianca tie for pairwise beating the greatest number of other candidates, '''3'''.
 
'''1<sup>st</sup> Degree:''' Ava and Bianca tie for the greatest totalsum differenceof inwin votesmargins for and againstover other tied finalists (both <math>29-29=0</math>).
 
'''2<sup>nd</sup> Degree:''' Ava and Bianca tie for the greatest totalsum differenceof inwin votesmargins for and againstover all other candidates (both <math>188204-149=3955</math>).
 
'''3<sup>rd</sup> Degree:''' Ava and Bianca tie for the least ''losing'' (and '''winning''') votes between them, ''149'' (and '''188204''').
 
'''4<sup>th</sup> Degree:''' The shortest beatpath from Ava to Bianca is Ava→Deegan→Bianca and the shortest beatpath from Bianca to Ava is Bianca→Cedric→Ava. The differencewin between the numbermargin of votes preferring Ava over Deegan and the number of votes preferring Deegan over Ava is <math>39-38=1</math>. From Deegan to Bianca, the differencewin margin is <math>37-31=6</math>. The sum of the differenceswin margins in the beatpath from Ava to Bianca (the total beatpath strength) is <math>1+6=7</math>. From Bianca to Cedric, the differencewin margin is <math>35-28=7</math>. From Cedric to Ava, the differencewin margin is <math>33-26=7</math>. The total beatpath strength from Bianca to Ava is <math>7+7=14</math>. Bianca has the greatest (sum of) total beatpath strength(s)strengths among tied candidates, so Bianca is elected.
 
== Presentation of results ==
Ranked Robin results can be broken down differently depending on whether there are any ties and how much detail is desired.
If there is a [[Condorcet winner criterion|Condorcet Winner]], then simply show each of the winner's pairwise matchups against other candidates. This can either be shown as percentage of total votes for each candidate in a given pairwise matchup, or as the percentage point difference in favor of the winner if there's a desire to show less information.
 
==== Two different ways to present the results of the same election with Condorcet Winner Ava ====
<blockquote>
 
Ava: 54%《》Bianca: 46%
 
Ava: 59%《》Cedric: 39%
 
Ava: 63%《》Deegan: 31%
 
Ava: 64%《》Eli: 22%
 
Ava: 64%《》Fabio: 13%
 
</blockquote><blockquote>
 
Ava vs. Bianca: +8% points
 
Ava vs. Cedric: +20% points
 
Ava vs. Deegan: +32% points
 
Ava vs. Eli: +42% points
 
Ava vs. Fabio: +51% points
 
=== If there is no tie ===
</blockquote>If there is no Condorcet Winner but a single candidate wins without any tiebreaker, show how many matchups each candidate won in addition to each of the winner's pairwise matchups.
Show how many matchups each candidate won and highlight the overall winner. Optionally, show the overall winner's margins over other candidates.
 
==== Example of how to present the results of an election where the winner Ava is not a Condorcet Winner ====
<blockquote>
 
Line 247 ⟶ 231:
 
Fabio lost all matchups
 
 
Ava is elected!
 
</blockquote><blockquote>
Line 260 ⟶ 247:
Ava vs. Fabio: +51% points
 
</blockquote>
</blockquote>These two scenarios will cover the vast majority of real-world elections.
 
=== If there's a tie ===
First show how many matchups each candidate won and highlight the finalists. Then, show each finalist's sum of win margins over other finalists and highlight the winner. Optionally, show each matchup among finalists including their win margins.<blockquote>
When there is a '''1<sup>st</sup> Degree''' tie, it's often a [[Condorcet paradox|Condorcet cycle]] (rock-paper-scissors-style tie) with more than two candidates (now finalists). In the case that there are only two finalists, present results as the above example without a Condorcet Winner, but highlight the matchup between the two finalists, which alone breaks the tie. Otherwise, present results according to the level desired as described below.
 
Ava won 4 matchups (against Bianca, Deegan, Eli, and Fabio)
'''Level 1:''' Simply state who the winner is.
 
Bianca won 4 matchups (against Cedric, Deegan, Eli, and Fabio)
'''Level 2:''' Show which candidates are finalists (and optionally which candidates were eliminated).
 
'''LevelCedric 3:'''won Show how many4 matchups each(against candidateAva, wonDeegan, asEli, shownand above.Fabio)
 
Deegan won 2 matchups (against Eli and Fabio)
'''Level 4:''' Show each finalist's total difference in votes for and against other finalists. These values can be given a name like "Total Advantage".
 
Eli won 1 matchups (against Fabio)
'''Level 5:''' Show the breakdown of each finalist's total difference in votes for and against other finalists by showing the difference within each finalist matchup. These values can be given a name like "Matchup Advantage"
 
Fabio lost all matchups
'''Level 6:''' Show a preference matrix that's just wins and losses (and ties).
 
'''Level 7:''' Show a preference matrix using percentages.
 
Ava, Bianca, and Cedric are finalists.
'''Level 8:''' Show the full preference matrix.
 
==== Example of showing Level 4 with 3 finalists in a Condorcet cycle ====
<blockquote>
 
Ava,'s Bianca,total andwin Cedricmargin areover other finalists: -23.5% points
 
Bianca's total win margin over other finalists: -3.3% points
 
AvaCedric's Totaltotal Advantagewin margin over other finalists: -23+26.58% points
 
Bianca's Total Advantage: -3.3% points
 
Cedric's Total Advantage: +26.8% points
 
 
Cedric is elected!
 
</blockquote><blockquote>
</blockquote>Note that all of the Total Advantages sum to 0. This can be used to check the math performed.
 
==== Example of showing Level 5 with 3 finalists in a Condorcet cycle ====
<blockquote>
 
Ava, Bianca, and Cedric are finalists.
Line 308 ⟶ 286:
Ava vs. Cedric: -45.6% points
 
Ava's Totaltotal Advantagewin margin over other finalists: -23.5% points
 
 
 
Line 315 ⟶ 294:
Bianca vs. Ava: -22.1% points
 
Bianca's Totaltotal Advantagewin margin over other finalists: -3.3% points
 
 
 
Line 322 ⟶ 302:
Cedric vs. Bianca: -18.8% points
 
Cedric's Totaltotal Advantagewin margin over other finalists: +26.8% points
 
 
 
Cedric is elected!
 
</blockquote>In the rare case of a '''2<sup>nd</sup> Degree''' tie, if there are many candidates, it is recommended to focus on who the tied finalists are and their Totalsum Advantagesof win margins over all other candidates (which likely will not sum to 0).
 
== Legal and economic viability ==
When legally defined as ''always'' reducing to a finalist set first and then electing the finalist with the greatest totalsum differenceof (Totalwin Advantage)margins amongover finalistsother finalist (as described in the '''1<sup>st</sup> Degree''' tiebreaker), Ranked Robin always elects a majority preferred winner, arguably including in cases of '''2<sup>nd</sup> Degree''' ties. This legal definition does not change the outcomes of Ranked Robin. Many municipalities in the [[United States]] are subject to a majority clause in their respective state's election code, often requiring those jurisdictions to run two or more elections for certain races. Ranked Robin can satisfy many of these majority clauses in a single election, allowing municipalities to eliminate an election if so desired, helping to offset the costs of implementing Ranked Robin, typically entirely within one election cycle.
 
If there is only 1 finalist, then they are voted for by a majority of voters who had a preference among finalists.
 
If there are multiple finalists, at least 1 finalist will have a positive Totalsum of win Advantagemargins and at least 1 finalist will have a negative Totalsum Advantageof win margins because the sum of advantagesall win margins will always equal 0. Because the finalist with the greatest Totalsum of win Advantagemargins is elected, that winner is guaranteed to have a positive Totalsum Advantageof win margins, demonstrating that, among finalists, they are a majority preferred winner.
 
If there is a '''2<sup>nd</sup> Degree''' tie, all of the finalists could potentially (but rarely) have a negative Totalsum Advantageof win margins when compared to all candidates, but it could be argued that because the ''finalist'' with the greatest Totalsum of win Advantagemargins is elected, the winner was voted for by a majority of voters who had a preference ''among finalists''. This argument is further strengthened in the case that exactly 2 finalists experience a '''2<sup>nd</sup> Degree''' tie, which covers almost all cases of '''2<sup>nd</sup> Degree''' ties. If this argument is found not to satisfy a particular majority clause, it may be desirable to leave the '''2<sup>nd</sup> Degree''' tiebreaker out of the legislation and legally declare a tie in the equivalent case of a '''2<sup>nd</sup> Degree''' tie, which is about as rare as a tie under [[First Past the Post electoral system|Choose-one Voting]].
 
Furthermore, in most cases with only 1 finalist, including all elections with a Condorcet Winner, the winner will be majority preferred over ''all'' other candidates because the winner’s Totalsum Advantageof win margins is positive; however, there are rare theoretical cases in which the only finalist has a negative Totalsum Advantageof win margins over all other candidates. If the “majority preferred among finalists” argument doesn’t legally hold when there’s only 1 finalist, then this rare case could either explicitly be denoted as not electing a majority winner (thus requiring an extra election to be run), or an alternative winner could be calculated by selecting the candidate with the greatest Totalsum of win Advantagemargins among all candidates (completely ignoring any reduction to a set of finalists).
 
== Criteria ==
Line 371 ⟶ 352:
 
=== A note on cloneproofness ===
TheRanked CopelandRobin componentcan failsfail clone independence byonly [[w:Independencein ofelections cloneswith criterion#Copeland|no Condorcet Winner, through [[crowding]] and [[teaming]]. It can be argued that a party stands nothing to gain (or lose) by running clones as far as the crowding vulnerability is concerned, because all a losing candidate A can achieve by triggering a clone failure is to change the candidatewinner from some B to some other C, which doesn't help A since A lost anyway -- (unless C just happens to be politically closer aligned withto A's position than does B does). However, in elections expected to lack a Condorcet Winner, the teaming incentive may be more conventionally exploitable, since it directly benefits a candidate who runs clones. If the there's expected to be a tie leading to more than one finalist, then this could allow teaming to succeed. For instance, consider this pre-cloning election:
Ranked Robin can fail clone independence in one of two ways: either by its Copeland component or by its Borda component.
 
The Copeland component fails clone independence by [[w:Independence of clones criterion#Copeland|crowding and teaming]]. It can be argued that a party stands nothing to gain (or lose) by running clones as far as the crowding vulnerability is concerned, because all a candidate A can achieve by triggering a clone failure is to change the candidate from some B to some other C, which doesn't help A since A lost anyway -- unless C just happens to be closer aligned with A's position than does B. However, the teaming incentive may be more conventionally exploitable, since it directly benefits a candidate who runs clones.
 
The Borda component fails clone independence by teaming. If the [[Copeland set]] consists of more than one candidate, as can happen with some Condorcet cycles, then this could expose the Borda component and allow teaming to succeed. For instance, consider this pre-cloning election:
 
{{ballots|
Line 383 ⟶ 360:
}}
 
The Copelandfinalists setare is {A, B, and C}. A and B tie for Bordasum scoreof win margins, but this can be shifted in favor of A by teaming, e.g.:
 
{{ballots|
Line 391 ⟶ 368:
}}
 
By "sacrificing" A2 to prevent B from becoming a finalist, A1 wins after the tiebreaker.
after which A wins.
 
Ranked Robin passes vote-splitting clone independence: cloning a candidate can't make that candidate lose.
Line 399 ⟶ 376:
* [https://www.reddit.com/r/EndFPTP/comments/qkamzm/new_condorcet_method_that_doesnt_require_a/ Ranked Robin thread on r/EndFPTP] (starting November 1, 2021)
* [https://www.votingtheory.org/forum/topic/136/new-simple-condorcet-method-basically-copeland-margins Ranked Robin thread on Voting Theory Forum] (starting October 25, 2021)
* [https://www.equal.vote/ranked_robin Explanation of Ranked Robin from the Equal Vote Coalition]
 
== References ==
Line 407 ⟶ 385:
[[Category:Condorcet methods]]
[[Category:Smith-efficient Condorcet methods]]
[[Category:Condorcet-related concepts]]

Latest revision as of 03:07, 30 June 2024

Ranked Robin is a Condorcet voting method focused on the presentation of the results such that everyday voters can understand them without extensive education. Ranked Robin uses a ranked ballot. Voters are free to rank multiple candidates equally on their ballots. The candidate who beats the most other candidates head-to-head is elected, much like a round-robin tournament.

History

Ranked Robin was invented by Sass on 30 September 2021 and named by Sara Wolk on 7 November 2021. As an enthusiast of cardinal voting methods and a strong advocate for voter empowerment, Sass saw a timely need for a sufficiently-accurate ranked voting method that was on par with the simplicity of voting methods like STAR Voting and even Approval Voting, particularly in the United States. Ranked Robin is nearly identical to the earliest known Condorcet method, invented by Ramon Llull in his 1299 treatise Ars Electionis[1], which was similarly replicated by Marquis de Condorcet centuries later, and then again by Arthur Herbert Copeland. A mathematically identical method to Ranked Robin including the first tie-breaking mechanic was described by Partha Dasgupta and Eric Maskin in 2004[2]. The primary innovation of Ranked Robin is the reduction and formatting of results in such a way that they are palatable to a general audience, as a full preference matrix can be overwhelming for most voters. This innovation can likely be adapted to simplify the results of other voting methods that use pairwise counting, particularly those that first restrict the set of winners such as Smith-efficient voting methods.

Balloting

Voters may rank as many candidates as they would like. Voters are free to rank multiple candidates equally. Skipped ranks are ignored and will neither hurt nor help a voter's vote. All candidates left unranked are considered tied for the last rank, below the lowest rank marked on a voter's ballot.

Local counting

Ranked Robin is summable through the use of preference matrices. Full preference matrices can be created simply by hand if needed and then reported directly to the media and the public, allowing ballots and ballot data to remain local for recounts and risk-limiting audits without risking the threat of vote selling and voter coercion[3]. This decentralization of tallying allows elections to remain robust against scaled election attacks, which is vital in jurisdictions that run geographically-spread or high-profile elections. In contrast, voting methods that are not precinct summable, like Ranked Choice (Instant Runoff) Voting and many expressive proportional voting methods, lose these benefits and can lead to distrust in election outcomes if fraud, attacks, or even simple mistakes happen under a centralized counting authority.

Tabulation

Elect the candidate who pairwise beats the greatest number of candidates.

Example election

8:Ava>Cedric>Deegan>Bianca>Eli

6:Ava=Bianca=Cedric>Eli>Deegan

6:Eli>Ava>Bianca=Cedric=Deegan

6:Deegan>Bianca=Cedric>Eli>Ava

4:Bianca>Ava>Eli>Deegan>Cedric

3:Eli>Deegan>Bianca=Cedric>Ava

2:Deegan=Eli>Bianca=Cedric>Ava

Create a preference matrix from the ballots.

Bold indicates wins, Italics indicates losses
# of voters who prefer Ava Bianca Cedric Deegan Eli
Ava over 14 18 24 18
Bianca over 15 4 10 24
Cedric over 11 8 14 20
Deegan over 11 19 15 14
Eli over 17 11 15 19

Ava pairwise beats the greatest number of candidates, 3, so she is elected as the winner.

Tie-breaking mechanics

Frequency of ties

Almost all public elections using Ranked Robin will not have any ties for the winning candidate. However, ties under Ranked Robin may potentially be more common than ties under Choose-one Voting. While there are 4 degrees of tiebreakers defined, ties after the 1st Degree tiebreaker are about as rare as ties under Choose-one Voting, and ties after the 2nd Degree tiebreaker are much rarer than that.

Degrees of ties

If there is a tie (including Condorcet cycles), use the 1st Degree tie-breaking method to resolve it. If there is still a tie, use the 2nd Degree tiebreaker, and so on.

1st Degree: Declare the tied candidates finalists. Elect the finalist with the greatest sum of win margins over the other finalists.

To find a win margin for a finalist in a matchup, subtract the number of votes ranking the opponent finalist higher from the number of votes ranking the finalist in question higher. Add these margins up for each finalist to find their sum of win margins. Note that any of these values can be positive or negative.

Since those two steps are both addition, they can also be combined into one step. For example, let   be the number of votes preferring finalist   over each other finalist (equivalent to the sum of the values in  's row in a preference matrix that consists only of finalists) and let   be the number of votes preferring each other finalist over   (equivalent to the sum of the values in  's column in a preference matrix that consists only of finalists);  's sum of win margins is  .

2nd Degree: Elect the tied finalist with the greatest sum of win margins over all candidates.

3rd Degree: It is highly unlikely that there will still be a tie after the 2nd Degree tiebreaker, but if there is, it is not recommended to use tie-breaking methods beyond the 2nd Degree tiebreaker for public elections as voter trust may be shaken more by using the 3rd Degree tiebreaker and beyond than drawing lots or hosting another election.

In the event that there is a tie after the 2nd Degree tiebreaker, the sum of win margins for the tied candidates will be the same, but the values used to calculate them will likely be different. Elect the tied finalist whose values are closest to the tied margins.

For example, if  ,  , and   are tied after the 2nd Degree tiebreaker, then   (where win margins are calculated across the entire field of candidates), but it's likely that   (and by proxy that  ). The tied candidate with the greatest number of votes against them will also have the greatest number of votes in favor of them, and the tied candidate with the fewest number of votes against them will have the fewest number of votes for them. Elect the tied candidate with the fewest number of votes on both metrics (for the motivation that they are the least polarizing tied candidate).

4th Degree: If there is still a tie after the 3rd Degree tiebreaker, it is unlikely that the 4th Degree tiebreaker will break that tie, as it will only work if the tied candidates have matchup losses against other candidates.

Find the shortest beatpath from each tied candidate to each other tied candidate. For each tied candidate, for each shortest beatpath to another tied candidate, for each pairwise victory in the beatpath, find the win margin. Sum these win margins within each selected beatpath to get the total strength of each selected beatpath. Sum each tied candidate's total beatpath strengths over other tied candidates. Elect the tied candidate with the greatest sum of beatpath strengths. (Every number in this calculation will be positive.) If there are multiple shortest beatpaths from one tied candidate to another, select the one with the lowest total strength.

Example of a ballot set that requires all 4 tie-breaking degrees

10: Eli>Deegan>Ava=Cedric>Fabio

9: Bianca=Deegan>Eli>Cedric

8: Deegan>Eli>Ava=Bianca=Cedric

8: Bianca>Ava>Fabio>Cedric

8: Fabio>Cedric>Ava>Deegan>Bianca

7: Ava>Eli>Bianca>Fabio

6: Fabio>Bianca=Cedric>Ava

6: Cedric>Deegan=Eli>Ava=Bianca>Fabio

5: Deegan>Ava=Bianca>Eli>Cedric

4: Cedric>Bianca>Ava

4: Ava>Bianca=Fabio

4: Ava=Bianca>Fabio

2: Bianca=Fabio>Ava=Eli

Here's the preference matrix:

Bold indicates wins, Italics indicates losses, Underline indicates ties
# of voters who prefer Ava Bianca Cedric Deegan Eli Fabio Row total (votes for)
Ava over 29 26 39 42 56 204
Bianca over 29 35 31 46 51 204
Cedric over 33 28 32 32 42 167
Deegan over 38 37 32 30 38 175
Eli over 33 31 41 19 45 169
Fabio over 16 24 39 39 32 150
Column total (votes against) 149 149 181 168 190 232 1069 - 1069 = 0

Ranked Robin: Ava and Bianca tie for pairwise beating the greatest number of other candidates, 3.

1st Degree: Ava and Bianca tie for the greatest sum of win margins over other finalists (both  ).

2nd Degree: Ava and Bianca tie for the greatest sum of win margins over all candidates (both  ).

3rd Degree: Ava and Bianca tie for the least losing (and winning) votes between them, 149 (and 204).

4th Degree: The shortest beatpath from Ava to Bianca is Ava→Deegan→Bianca and the shortest beatpath from Bianca to Ava is Bianca→Cedric→Ava. The win margin of Ava over Deegan is  . From Deegan to Bianca, the win margin is  . The sum of the win margins in the beatpath from Ava to Bianca (the total beatpath strength) is  . From Bianca to Cedric, the win margin is  . From Cedric to Ava, the win margin is  . The total beatpath strength from Bianca to Ava is  . Bianca has the greatest sum of beatpath strengths among tied candidates, so Bianca is elected.

Presentation of results

Ranked Robin results can be broken down differently depending on whether there are any ties and how much detail is desired.

If there is no tie

Show how many matchups each candidate won and highlight the overall winner. Optionally, show the overall winner's margins over other candidates.

Ava won 4 matchups (against Cedric, Deegan, Eli, and Fabio)

Bianca won 3 matchups (against Ava, Eli, and Fabio)

Cedric won 3 matchups (against Bianca, Eli, and Fabio)

Deegan won 3 matchups (against Bianca, Cedric, and Fabio)

Eli won 2 matchups (against Deegan and Fabio)

Fabio lost all matchups


Ava is elected!

Ava vs. Bianca: -6% points

Ava vs. Cedric: +20% points

Ava vs. Deegan: +32% points

Ava vs. Eli: +42% points

Ava vs. Fabio: +51% points

If there's a tie

First show how many matchups each candidate won and highlight the finalists. Then, show each finalist's sum of win margins over other finalists and highlight the winner. Optionally, show each matchup among finalists including their win margins.

Ava won 4 matchups (against Bianca, Deegan, Eli, and Fabio)

Bianca won 4 matchups (against Cedric, Deegan, Eli, and Fabio)

Cedric won 4 matchups (against Ava, Deegan, Eli, and Fabio)

Deegan won 2 matchups (against Eli and Fabio)

Eli won 1 matchups (against Fabio)

Fabio lost all matchups


Ava, Bianca, and Cedric are finalists.


Ava's total win margin over other finalists: -23.5% points

Bianca's total win margin over other finalists: -3.3% points

Cedric's total win margin over other finalists: +26.8% points


Cedric is elected!

Ava, Bianca, and Cedric are finalists.


Ava vs. Bianca: +22.1% points

Ava vs. Cedric: -45.6% points

Ava's total win margin over other finalists: -23.5% points


Bianca vs. Cedric: +18.8% points

Bianca vs. Ava: -22.1% points

Bianca's total win margin over other finalists: -3.3% points


Cedric vs. Ava: +45.6% points

Cedric vs. Bianca: -18.8% points

Cedric's total win margin over other finalists: +26.8% points


Cedric is elected!

In the rare case of a 2nd Degree tie, if there are many candidates, it is recommended to focus on who the tied finalists are and their sum of win margins over all candidates (which likely will not sum to 0).

Legal and economic viability

When legally defined as always reducing to a finalist set first and then electing the finalist with the greatest sum of win margins over other finalist (as described in the 1st Degree tiebreaker), Ranked Robin always elects a majority preferred winner, arguably including in cases of 2nd Degree ties. This legal definition does not change the outcomes of Ranked Robin. Many municipalities in the United States are subject to a majority clause in their respective state's election code, often requiring those jurisdictions to run two or more elections for certain races. Ranked Robin can satisfy many of these majority clauses in a single election, allowing municipalities to eliminate an election if so desired, helping to offset the costs of implementing Ranked Robin, typically entirely within one election cycle.

If there is only 1 finalist, then they are voted for by a majority of voters who had a preference among finalists.

If there are multiple finalists, at least 1 finalist will have a positive sum of win margins and at least 1 finalist will have a negative sum of win margins because the sum of all win margins will always equal 0. Because the finalist with the greatest sum of win margins is elected, that winner is guaranteed to have a positive sum of win margins, demonstrating that, among finalists, they are a majority preferred winner.

If there is a 2nd Degree tie, all of the finalists could potentially (but rarely) have a negative sum of win margins when compared to all candidates, but it could be argued that because the finalist with the greatest sum of win margins is elected, the winner was voted for by a majority of voters who had a preference among finalists. This argument is further strengthened in the case that exactly 2 finalists experience a 2nd Degree tie, which covers almost all cases of 2nd Degree ties. If this argument is found not to satisfy a particular majority clause, it may be desirable to leave the 2nd Degree tiebreaker out of the legislation and legally declare a tie in the equivalent case of a 2nd Degree tie, which is about as rare as a tie under Choose-one Voting.

Furthermore, in most cases with only 1 finalist, including all elections with a Condorcet Winner, the winner will be majority preferred over all other candidates because the winner’s sum of win margins is positive; however, there are rare theoretical cases in which the only finalist has a negative sum of win margins over all other candidates. If the “majority preferred among finalists” argument doesn’t legally hold when there’s only 1 finalist, then this rare case could either explicitly be denoted as not electing a majority winner (thus requiring an extra election to be run), or an alternative winner could be calculated by selecting the candidate with the greatest sum of win margins among all candidates (completely ignoring any reduction to a set of finalists).

Criteria

Passed

Failed

A note on cloneproofness

Ranked Robin can fail clone independence only in elections with no Condorcet Winner, through crowding and teaming. It can be argued that a party stands nothing to gain (or lose) by running clones as far as the crowding vulnerability is concerned because all a losing candidate A can achieve by triggering a clone failure is to change the winner from some B to some other C, which doesn't help A since A lost anyway (unless C happens to be politically closer to A than B does). However, in elections expected to lack a Condorcet Winner, the teaming incentive may be exploitable since it directly benefits a candidate who runs clones. If the there's expected to be a tie leading to more than one finalist, then this could allow teaming to succeed. For instance, consider this pre-cloning election:

12: A>B>C>D>E>F
11: B>C>A>D>E>F
10: C>A>B>D>E>F

The finalists are A, B, and C. A and B tie for sum of win margins, but this can be shifted in favor of A by teaming:

12: A1>A2>B>C>D>E>F
11: B>C>A1>A2>D>E>F
10: C>A1>A2>B>D>E>F

By "sacrificing" A2 to prevent B from becoming a finalist, A1 wins after the tiebreaker.

Ranked Robin passes vote-splitting clone independence: cloning a candidate can't make that candidate lose.

External links

References

  1. G. Hägele & F. Pukelsheim (2001). "Llull's writings on electoral systems". Studia Lulliana. 41: 3–38.
  2. Maskin, Eric; Dasgupta, Partha (2004). "The Fairest Vote of All". Scientific American (290): 64–69 – via Harvard University.
  3. See Ballotpedia's "Intimidation of voters" article for more about voter coercion.