Spatial models of voting: Difference between revisions

Added lede from Yee diagram (rev: https://electowiki.org/w/index.php?title=Yee_diagram&oldid=16705 ) and Dimensional limitations of the spatial model (rev https://electowiki.org/w/index.php?title=Dimensional_limitations_of_the_spatial_model&oldid=16704 ) to create #Yee diagrams and #Limitations sections of this article
(Copied Political spectrum#Spatial modeling section from https://electowiki.org/w/index.php?title=Political_spectrum&oldid=16708)
(Added lede from Yee diagram (rev: https://electowiki.org/w/index.php?title=Yee_diagram&oldid=16705 ) and Dimensional limitations of the spatial model (rev https://electowiki.org/w/index.php?title=Dimensional_limitations_of_the_spatial_model&oldid=16704 ) to create #Yee diagrams and #Limitations sections of this article)
Line 5:
 
The number of candidates and the dimensionality of the space impose [[Dimensional limitations of the spatial model|fundamental limitations]] on the information content of ballots, as well as the commensurability of their information content.
== Spatial modelmodeling ==
 
== Political modeling ==
:''see also: [[Political spectrum]]''
Spatial modeling attempts to show the perceptions and decisions of voters when issue voting strategies are used in elections.<ref>{{cite journal | last1 = Cho | first1 = Sungdai | last2 = Endersby | first2 = James W. | title = Issues, the spatial theory of voting, and British general elections: a comparison of proximity and directional models | journal = Public Choice | volume = 114 | issue = 3 | pages = 275–293 | doi = 10.1023/A:1022616323373 | jstor = 30025956 | date = March 2003 | ref = harv |url=|via=}}</ref>{{Rp|275}} Spatial modeling assumes that if someone’s issue preferences are placed on a hypothetical spatial field along with all possible candidates’ policy positions, the individual will vote for the candidate whose political stances are closest to their own.<ref name=":0" />{{Rp|94}}<ref>{{cite journal | last = McCullough | first = B. Claire | title = Effects of variables using panel data: a review of techniques | journal = Public Opinion Quarterly | volume = 42 | issue = 2 | pages = 199–220 | doi = 10.1086/268443 | date = Summer 1978 | ref = harv |url=|via=}}</ref>Spacial modeling puts voters and candidates in a multi-dimensional space, where each dimension represents a single political issue,<ref name=":1">{{Cite journal|last=Davis|first=Otto A.|last2=Hinich|first2=Melvin J.|last3=Ordeshook|first3=Peter C.|date=1970-01-01|title=An Expository Development of a Mathematical Model of the Electoral Process|url=https://semanticscholar.org/paper/66661f9678dbe956e525e87a50b5b4ee6bf280f1|journal=The American Political Science Review|volume=64|issue=2|pages=426–448|doi=10.2307/1953842|jstor=1953842|quote=Since our model is multi-dimensional, we can incorporate all criteria which we normally associate with a citizen's voting decision process — issues, style, partisan identification, and the like.}}</ref><ref>{{Cite journal|last=Stoetzer|first=Lukas F.|last2=Zittlau|first2=Steffen|date=2015-07-01|title=Multidimensional Spatial Voting with Non-separable Preferences|url=https://www.cambridge.org/core/journals/political-analysis/article/multidimensional-spatial-voting-with-nonseparable-preferences/112FA71B889588C52C011CE7CEBBDAF2|journal=Political Analysis|volume=23|issue=3|pages=415–428|doi=10.1093/pan/mpv013|issn=1047-1987|quote=The spatial model of voting is ''the'' work horse for theories and empirical models in many fields of political science research, such as the equilibrium analysis in mass elections ... the estimation of legislators’ ideal points ... and the study of voting behavior. ... Its generalization to the multidimensional policy space, the Weighted Euclidean Distance (WED) model ... forms the stable theoretical foundation upon which nearly all present variations, extensions, and applications of multidimensional spatial voting rest.|via=}}</ref> sub-component of an issue,<ref>If voter preferences have more than one peak along a dimension, it needs to be decomposed into multiple dimensions that each only have a single peak. "We can satisfy our assumption about the form of the loss function if we increase the dimensionality of the analysis — by decomposing one dimension into two or more"</ref> or candidate attribute,<ref>{{Cite journal|last=Tideman|first=T|last2=Plassmann|first2=Florenz|date=June 2008|title=The Source of Election Results: An Empirical Analysis of Statistical Models of Voter Behavior|url=https://www.researchgate.net/publication/228920943|quote=Assume that voters care about the “attributes” of candidates. These attributes form a multi-dimensional “attribute space.”|via=}}</ref> even including non-political properties of the candidates, such as perceived corruption, health, etc.<ref name=":1" /> Voters are then modeled as having an ''ideal point'' in this space, with a preference distance between themselves and each candidate (usually [[W:Euclidean distance|Euclidean distance]]), i.e. a voter may be closer to a candidate on gun control, but disagree on abortion. Voters are then modeled as voting for the candidates whose attributes or policy proposals are nearest to their ideal point (or [[Tactical voting|strategically voting]] to try to minimize their distance to the actual winner).<ref>{{Cite web|url=https://www.pitt.edu/~woon/courses/ps2703_Lec4.pdf|title=Introduction to spatial modeling|last=Woon|first=Jonathan|date=|website=University of Pittsburgh|url-status=live|archive-url=|archive-date=|access-date=}}</ref> Other models that follow the idea of “closeness” are called proximity models.<ref name=":0">{{cite journal | last1 = Rabinowitz | first1 = George | last2 = Macdonald | first2 = Stuart Elaine | title = A directional theory of issue voting | journal = American Political Science Review | volume = 83 | issue = 1 | pages = 93–121 | doi = 10.2307/1956436 | jstor = 1956436 | date = March 1989 | ref = harv |url=|via=}}</ref>{{Rp|93, 96}}
 
 
== Spatial model ==
{{main|Spatial model of voting}}
 
The '''spatial model of voting''' puts voters and candidates in a multi-dimensional space, where each dimension represents a single political issue,<ref name=":1">{{Cite journal|last=Davis|first=Otto A.|last2=Hinich|first2=Melvin J.|last3=Ordeshook|first3=Peter C.|date=1970-01-01|title=An Expository Development of a Mathematical Model of the Electoral Process|url=https://semanticscholar.org/paper/66661f9678dbe956e525e87a50b5b4ee6bf280f1|journal=The American Political Science Review|volume=64|issue=2|pages=426–448|doi=10.2307/1953842|jstor=1953842|quote=Since our model is multi-dimensional, we can incorporate all criteria which we normally associate with a citizen's voting decision process — issues, style, partisan identification, and the like.}}</ref><ref>{{Cite journal|last=Stoetzer|first=Lukas F.|last2=Zittlau|first2=Steffen|date=2015-07-01|title=Multidimensional Spatial Voting with Non-separable Preferences|url=https://www.cambridge.org/core/journals/political-analysis/article/multidimensional-spatial-voting-with-nonseparable-preferences/112FA71B889588C52C011CE7CEBBDAF2|journal=Political Analysis|volume=23|issue=3|pages=415–428|doi=10.1093/pan/mpv013|issn=1047-1987|quote=The spatial model of voting is ''the'' work horse for theories and empirical models in many fields of political science research, such as the equilibrium analysis in mass elections ... the estimation of legislators’ ideal points ... and the study of voting behavior. ... Its generalization to the multidimensional policy space, the Weighted Euclidean Distance (WED) model ... forms the stable theoretical foundation upon which nearly all present variations, extensions, and applications of multidimensional spatial voting rest.|via=}}</ref> sub-component of an issue,<ref>If voter preferences have more than one peak along a dimension, it needs to be decomposed into multiple dimensions that each only have a single peak. "We can satisfy our assumption about the form of the loss function if we increase the dimensionality of the analysis — by decomposing one dimension into two or more"</ref> or candidate attribute,<ref>{{Cite journal|last=Tideman|first=T|last2=Plassmann|first2=Florenz|date=June 2008|title=The Source of Election Results: An Empirical Analysis of Statistical Models of Voter Behavior|url=https://www.researchgate.net/publication/228920943|quote=Assume that voters care about the “attributes” of candidates. These attributes form a multi-dimensional “attribute space.”|via=}}</ref> even including non-political properties of the candidates, such as perceived corruption, health, etc.<ref name=":1" /> Voters are then modeled as having an ''ideal point'' in this space, with a preference distance between themselves and each candidate (usually [[W:Euclidean distance|Euclidean distance]]), i.e. a voter may be closer to a candidate on gun control, but disagree on abortion. Voters are then modeled as voting for the candidates whose attributes or policy proposals are nearest to their ideal point (or [[Tactical voting|strategically voting]] to try to minimize their distance to the actual winner).<ref>{{Cite web|url=https://www.pitt.edu/~woon/courses/ps2703_Lec4.pdf|title=Introduction to spatial modeling|last=Woon|first=Jonathan|date=|website=University of Pittsburgh|url-status=live|archive-url=|archive-date=|access-date=}}</ref> Other models that follow the idea of “closeness” are called proximity models.<ref name=":0">{{cite journal | last1 = Rabinowitz | first1 = George | last2 = Macdonald | first2 = Stuart Elaine | title = A directional theory of issue voting | journal = American Political Science Review | volume = 83 | issue = 1 | pages = 93–121 | doi = 10.2307/1956436 | jstor = 1956436 | date = March 1989 | ref = harv |url=|via=}}</ref>{{Rp|93, 96}}
 
Mathematically (and spatially), a line on a political spectrum can be defined by:
Line 24 ⟶ 17:
Ultimately, these are projections of [[Spatial model of voting|a multi-dimensional political space]] onto a space of fewer dimensions, to generalize and make discussion simpler.
 
=== One-dimensional= ==
 
===One-dimensional===
{{main|Left-right political spectrum}}
{{wikipedia|Left-wing politics}}
Line 34 ⟶ 26:
Using the formulas above: n=1, v(x)=1, and d(x,y)=|x-y|. The directions on this spectrum are normally referred to as left and right.
 
==== Horseshoe theory ====
:''mainMain article: [[horseshoe theory]]''
 
What is often called the "[[horseshoe theory]]" claims that the extreme authoritarian economic left (Communism) is adjacent or close to extreme authoritarian economic right (neo-reactionism/fascism). A classification that follows this thought must then place these two close by or next to each other: either by using dimensions where they naturally fit next to each other, or by making opinion space curved so that going in the direction of fascism leads to Communism.
 
=== Two-dimensional= ==
{{wikipedia|Nolan chart}}
{{wikipedia|The Poltical Compass}}
{{wikipedia|Pournelle chart}}
 
While the [[Spatial model of voting#Horseshoe theory|"horseshoe theory" noted above]] appears two-dimensional, it is obviously just a variation on the [[left-right political spectrum]], which is uni-dimensional.
 
There are many two-dimensional political spaces, many of which have enough credible citations to have articles on [[English Wikipedia]]. These include the following:
Line 53 ⟶ 45:
The ''Nolan chart'' and ''the Political Compass'' are two popular examples, which can be seen as rotated versions of each other. The ''Pournelle chart'' is another variation with a different set of axes. Other two-dimensional models are described below.
 
==== ThreeYee Telosdiagrams Model ====
{{Main|Yee diagram}}[[File:Yee diagram IrvSq2.png|thumb|A Yee diagram of [[IRV]] with four candidates, showing that the Yellow candidate has been [[Center squeeze|squeezed out]] and cannot win.]]The "Yee diagram" (named after [[Ka-Ping Yee]]) is used to illustrate the behavior of election methods, given a fixed set of candidates in a [[Spatial model of voting|two-dimensional preference space]].<ref>{{Cite web|url=http://zesty.ca/voting/sim/|title=Voting Simulation Visualizations|last=Yee|first=Ka-Ping|date=2006-12-08|website=zesty.ca|url-status=live|archive-url=|archive-date=|access-date=2020-04-06}}</ref>
 
=== Three Telos Model ===
{{Main|Three Telos Model}}
[[File:Politics_map_triangle1.png|alt=|thumb]]
Line 68 ⟶ 63:
[[File:TelosTriangle.png|alt=|thumb|As in the two dimensional maps like the political compass, the differing ideologies can be put onto this map.]]
 
=== Three or higher dimensions ===
Political opinion can be divided into essentially any number of dimensions. Some other examples include the 3-dimensional [https://sapplyvalues.github.io Sapply Compass], the 4-dimensional [https://8values.github.io/ 8values] space, and the [https://9axes.github.io/ 9Axes] space.
 
Line 81 ⟶ 76:
In the end, it is difficult to model the behaviors of human beings in such a way that they can be reduced to simple numbers and political spectra as lines on a graph.
 
== Limitations ==
{{Main|Dimensional limitations of the spatial model}}
The [[Spatial model of voting|spatial model]] is ubiquitous in theoretical study and simulations of voting methods. However, the dimension of this geometric embedding imposes fundamental restrictions on the allowed number of candidates which may be distinguished, as there is a finite number of regions possible for each possible ranking. The following article discusses this limitation and some implications.
 
== See also==