Symmetrical ICT: Difference between revisions

Content added Content deleted
No edit summary
No edit summary
Line 1: Line 1:
'''Symmetrical ICT''', short for '''Symmetrical Improved Condorcet, Top''' is a voting method designed by [[Mike Ossipoff|Michael Ossipoff]]. <!-- when? link to EM? --> It is based on Kevin Venzke's concept of "Improved Condorcet", which is a modification of pairwise comparison logic that enables methods to pass the [[favorite betrayal criterion]] at the cost of sometimes failing the [[Condorcet criterion]].
'''Symmetrical ICT''', short for '''Symmetrical Improved Condorcet, Top''' is a voting method designed by [[Mike Ossipoff|Michael Ossipoff]]. <!-- when? link to EM? --> It is based on Kevin Venzke's concept of "Improved Condorcet", which is a modification of pairwise comparison logic that enables methods to pass the [[favorite betrayal criterion]] at the cost of sometimes failing the [[Condorcet criterion]].


However, Symmetrical ICT doesn't actually pass the [[favorite betrayal criterion]].{{Cn}}
However, Symmetrical ICT doesn't actually pass the [[favorite betrayal criterion]] (as shown below).


==Definition==
==Definition==
Line 28: Line 28:
== Improved Condorcet ==
== Improved Condorcet ==


Condorcet methods usually have a low but nonzero rate of [[favorite betrayal]] failures.<ref>{{cite web|url=http://lists.electorama.com/pipermail/election-methods-electorama.com/2005-June/114476.html|title=Measuring the risk of strict ranking|website=Election-methods mailing list archives|date=2005-06-28|last=Venzke|first=K.}}</ref> '''Improved Condorcet''' is a modification of pairwise comparisons in an otherwise Condorcet-compliant method to turn absolute Condorcet compliance and a low rate of [[FBC]] failure into absolute FBC compliance and a low rate of [[Condorcet criterion]] failures.
Condorcet methods usually have a low but nonzero rate of [[favorite betrayal]] failures.<ref>{{cite web|url=http://lists.electorama.com/pipermail/election-methods-electorama.com/2005-June/114476.html|title=Measuring the risk of strict ranking|website=Election-methods mailing list archives|date=2005-06-28|last=Venzke|first=K.}}</ref> '''Improved Condorcet''' is a modification of pairwise comparisons in an otherwise Condorcet-compliant method to turn absolute Condorcet compliance and a low rate of [[FBC]] failure into absolute FBC compliance and a low rate of [[Condorcet criterion]] failures (along with absolute Majority Condorcet compliance).


Mike Ossipoff argued that improved Condorcet allows a voter who wants one of X and Y to win, and who ranks X first, to change a ranking of X>Y into X=Y without undue risk that this will change the winner from Y to someone lower ranked by that voter; and thus that it's better to satisfy the IC version of Condorcet than the actual [[Condorcet criterion]].
Mike Ossipoff argued that improved Condorcet allows a voter who wants one of X and Y to win, and who ranks X first, to change a ranking of X>Y into X=Y without undue risk that this will change the winner from Y to someone lower ranked by that voter; and thus that it's better to satisfy the IC version of Condorcet than the actual [[Condorcet criterion]].
Line 43: Line 43:


It was intended to pass the [[favorite betrayal criterion]], but doesn't succeed in doing so due to the "(X>Y) > (Y>X)" term in the definition. It is possible that a voter can lower their favorite from the top and thereby make their compromise the only candidate who isn't "beaten."
It was intended to pass the [[favorite betrayal criterion]], but doesn't succeed in doing so due to the "(X>Y) > (Y>X)" term in the definition. It is possible that a voter can lower their favorite from the top and thereby make their compromise the only candidate who isn't "beaten."

=== Favorite betrayal example ===
0.389: B>A=C
0.290: A>C>B
0.241: C>B>A
0.079: A≥C>B ⇒ C>A=B
In this case, the voters on the bottom row can elect a better candidate, C, by reversing their preference for A.


==Notes==
==Notes==