Talk:Dominant mutual third set: Difference between revisions

From electowiki
Content added Content deleted
(Created page with "== Possible multi-winner generalizations == User:Kristomun, I think this may have some kind of STV-PR generalization. In a 2-seat election, we know that anyone who has ov...")
 
(→‎Smith-efficiency: new section)
Line 2: Line 2:


[[User:Kristomun]], I think this may have some kind of STV-PR generalization. In a 2-seat election, we know that anyone who has over 1/4th of the active votes at any point in STV is guaranteed to be one of the final 3 remaining candidates, since it's impossible for 3 other candidates to each have more votes than this candidate (since they'd each have to have over 1/4th of the active votes, resulting in more than 100% of votes total being allocated to different candidates), which is what would enable them to survive elimination longer. So, we can say that when over 1/3rds of the voters prefer someone from the "dominant mutual quarter" set (DMT but for 1/4th of the electorate) over anyone else who survives until the final round, then the dominant mutual quarter candidate must win. In general, someone who is preferred by a solid coalition of 1/(k+2)th of the voters (k being the number of seats) and preferred by 1/(k+1)th of all voters over any other given rival must win. I'm not sure if there's a way to extract more from this insight, though. [[User:BetterVotingAdvocacy|BetterVotingAdvocacy]] ([[User talk:BetterVotingAdvocacy|talk]]) 03:48, 27 March 2020 (UTC)
[[User:Kristomun]], I think this may have some kind of STV-PR generalization. In a 2-seat election, we know that anyone who has over 1/4th of the active votes at any point in STV is guaranteed to be one of the final 3 remaining candidates, since it's impossible for 3 other candidates to each have more votes than this candidate (since they'd each have to have over 1/4th of the active votes, resulting in more than 100% of votes total being allocated to different candidates), which is what would enable them to survive elimination longer. So, we can say that when over 1/3rds of the voters prefer someone from the "dominant mutual quarter" set (DMT but for 1/4th of the electorate) over anyone else who survives until the final round, then the dominant mutual quarter candidate must win. In general, someone who is preferred by a solid coalition of 1/(k+2)th of the voters (k being the number of seats) and preferred by 1/(k+1)th of all voters over any other given rival must win. I'm not sure if there's a way to extract more from this insight, though. [[User:BetterVotingAdvocacy|BetterVotingAdvocacy]] ([[User talk:BetterVotingAdvocacy|talk]]) 03:48, 27 March 2020 (UTC)

== Smith-efficiency ==

[[User:BetterVotingAdvocacy]], I don't think what you said is true: that electing from the DMT set implies Smith when the Smith set is a subset of the DMT set is. Consider e.g. an election where more than a third of the voters vote ABCD in some order above everybody else, and that there are say, 26 candidates. Suppose furthermore that each voter in a majority votes (some random permutation of a random subset of candidates E..Z) > (some permutation of A, B, and C) > D > everybody else. Now {A,B,C,D} is the smallest DMT set, but D is beaten pairwise by A, B, and C, and thus D is not in the Smith set. So the Smith set is {A,B,C} which is a subset of the smallest DMT set {A,B,C,D}. Then our contrived DMT-passing method could elect D, which would be in the DMT set but not the Smith set.

E.g.
{{ballots|
12: D>B>C>A>E>F>G>H>I
11: A>B>C>D>E>F>G>H>I
11: C>A>B>D>E>F>G>H>I
20: E>A>B>C>D
20: F>B>C>A>D
20: G>C>A>B>D}}

Or the obligatory anti-IRV example:

{{ballots|
12:D>A>B>C>E>F>G
11:D>B>A>C>E>F>G
11:C>D>A>B>E>F>G
19:E>A>B>C>D>F>G
21:F>B>C>A>D>E>G
20:G>C>A>B>D>E>F}}

Here the smallest DMT set is {ABCD}. IRV elects D. The Smith set is {ABC}. [[User:Kristomun|Kristomun]] ([[User talk:Kristomun|talk]]) 22:10, 8 May 2020 (UTC)

Revision as of 22:10, 8 May 2020

Possible multi-winner generalizations

User:Kristomun, I think this may have some kind of STV-PR generalization. In a 2-seat election, we know that anyone who has over 1/4th of the active votes at any point in STV is guaranteed to be one of the final 3 remaining candidates, since it's impossible for 3 other candidates to each have more votes than this candidate (since they'd each have to have over 1/4th of the active votes, resulting in more than 100% of votes total being allocated to different candidates), which is what would enable them to survive elimination longer. So, we can say that when over 1/3rds of the voters prefer someone from the "dominant mutual quarter" set (DMT but for 1/4th of the electorate) over anyone else who survives until the final round, then the dominant mutual quarter candidate must win. In general, someone who is preferred by a solid coalition of 1/(k+2)th of the voters (k being the number of seats) and preferred by 1/(k+1)th of all voters over any other given rival must win. I'm not sure if there's a way to extract more from this insight, though. BetterVotingAdvocacy (talk) 03:48, 27 March 2020 (UTC)

Smith-efficiency

User:BetterVotingAdvocacy, I don't think what you said is true: that electing from the DMT set implies Smith when the Smith set is a subset of the DMT set is. Consider e.g. an election where more than a third of the voters vote ABCD in some order above everybody else, and that there are say, 26 candidates. Suppose furthermore that each voter in a majority votes (some random permutation of a random subset of candidates E..Z) > (some permutation of A, B, and C) > D > everybody else. Now {A,B,C,D} is the smallest DMT set, but D is beaten pairwise by A, B, and C, and thus D is not in the Smith set. So the Smith set is {A,B,C} which is a subset of the smallest DMT set {A,B,C,D}. Then our contrived DMT-passing method could elect D, which would be in the DMT set but not the Smith set.

E.g.

12: D>B>C>A>E>F>G>H>I
11: A>B>C>D>E>F>G>H>I
11: C>A>B>D>E>F>G>H>I
20: E>A>B>C>D
20: F>B>C>A>D
20: G>C>A>B>D

Or the obligatory anti-IRV example:

12:D>A>B>C>E>F>G
11:D>B>A>C>E>F>G
11:C>D>A>B>E>F>G
19:E>A>B>C>D>F>G
21:F>B>C>A>D>E>G
20:G>C>A>B>D>E>F

Here the smallest DMT set is {ABCD}. IRV elects D. The Smith set is {ABC}. Kristomun (talk) 22:10, 8 May 2020 (UTC)