Display title | Independence of Smith-dominated alternatives |
Default sort key | Independence of Smith-dominated alternatives |
Page length (in bytes) | 4,357 |
Namespace ID | 0 |
Page ID | 1778 |
Page content language | en - English |
Page content model | wikitext |
Indexing by robots | Allowed |
Number of redirects to this page | 2 |
Counted as a content page | Yes |
Number of subpages of this page | 0 (0 redirects; 0 non-redirects) |
Page views in the past month | 0 |
Edit | Allow all users (infinite) |
Move | Allow all users (infinite) |
Delete | Allow all users (infinite) |
Page creator | BetterVotingAdvocacy (talk | contribs) |
Date of page creation | 07:16, 22 February 2020 |
Latest editor | RobLa (talk | contribs) |
Date of latest edit | 09:30, 16 May 2021 |
Total number of edits | 7 |
Recent number of edits (within past 180 days) | 0 |
Recent number of distinct authors | 0 |
Transcluded template (1) | Template used on this page:
|
Description | Content |
Article description: (description ) This attribute controls the content of the description and og:description elements. | Independence of Smith-dominated alternatives (ISDA), also sometimes called Smith-IIA (Smith-Independence of Irrelevant Alternatives), says that if one option (X) wins an election, and a new alternative (Y) is added, X will still win the election if Y is not in the Smith set. ISDA implies Smith and thus Condorcet, since logically speaking, if an ISDA-passing method's winner were not in the Smith set, eliminating everyone outside of the Smith set would have to change the winner. Some Condorcet methods (e.g. Schulze) satisfy ISDA. |